alliance portfolio diversity and firm...

33
ALLIANCE PORTFOLIO DIVERSITY AND FIRM PERFORMANCE Ruihua Joy Jiang School of Business Administration Oakland University 2200 N. Squirrel Rd. Rochester, MI 48309 Phone: 248-370-2832 Fax: 248-370-4275 Email: [email protected] And Qingjiu Tom Tao College of Business and Economics Lehigh University 621 Taylor St. Bethlehem, PA 18015 Phone: 610-758-3438 Fax: 610-758-6941 Email: [email protected] And Michael D. Santoro College of Business and Economics Lehigh University 621 Taylor Street Bethlehem, PA 18015 Phone: 610-758-6414 Fax: 610-758-6941 Email: [email protected] Running Head: Research Notes and Commentaries 0

Upload: votram

Post on 14-Mar-2018

216 views

Category:

Documents


3 download

TRANSCRIPT

Page 1: ALLIANCE PORTFOLIO DIVERSITY AND FIRM ...sbafaculty.oakland.edu/Directory/jiang12/intellcont/Jiang... · Web viewCorporate-level three-year average of net profit margin (2000-2002

ALLIANCE PORTFOLIO DIVERSITY AND FIRM PERFORMANCE

Ruihua Joy JiangSchool of Business Administration

Oakland University2200 N. Squirrel Rd. Rochester, MI 48309

Phone: 248-370-2832Fax: 248-370-4275

Email: [email protected]

And

Qingjiu Tom TaoCollege of Business and Economics

Lehigh University621 Taylor St. Bethlehem, PA 18015

Phone: 610-758-3438Fax: 610-758-6941

Email: [email protected]

And

Michael D. SantoroCollege of Business and Economics

Lehigh University621 Taylor Street

Bethlehem, PA 18015Phone: 610-758-6414Fax: 610-758-6941

Email: [email protected]

Running Head: Research Notes and Commentaries

Keywords: alliance portfolio diversity, partner diversity, functional diversity, governance

diversity, diversity and performance, auto industry

0

Page 2: ALLIANCE PORTFOLIO DIVERSITY AND FIRM ...sbafaculty.oakland.edu/Directory/jiang12/intellcont/Jiang... · Web viewCorporate-level three-year average of net profit margin (2000-2002

ABSTRACT

In this paper, we propose a comprehensive alliance portfolio diversity construct that include

partner, functional, and governance diversity. Ground our work primarily with the resource- and

dynamic capabilities-based views, we argue that increased diversity in partners’ industry,

organizational, and national background will incur added complexity and coordination costs as

well as broadened resource and learning benefits. Increased functional diversity results in a

balanced portfolio while increased governance diversity inhibits learning and routine building.

Hypotheses were tested with alliance portfolio and performance data for 138 multinational firms

in the global automobile industry during the twenty-year period from 1985 to 2005. We found

alliance portfolios with greater organizational and functional diversity and lower governance

diversity to be related to higher firm performance. Industry diversity had a U-shape relationship

to firm performance. We suggest that firms manage their alliance with a clear portfolio

perspective, seeking to maximize resource and learning benefits by collaborating with a variety

of organizations in various value-chain activities while minimizing managerial costs with a

focused set of organizing structures.

1

Page 3: ALLIANCE PORTFOLIO DIVERSITY AND FIRM ...sbafaculty.oakland.edu/Directory/jiang12/intellcont/Jiang... · Web viewCorporate-level three-year average of net profit margin (2000-2002

INTRODUCTION

Research on strategic alliances has proliferated commensurate with increasing use (Lavie, 2007).

The majority of the strategic alliance literature can be categorized into two main streams. The

first focuses on the alliance as the principal unit of analysis, examining determinants of alliance

formation, governance, management, and performance. The second adopts a network

perspective, exploring outcome implications of a firm’s position in a network of cooperative

relationships. While both aid our understanding of strategic alliances, recently emerging is a firm

level perspective where a firm’s alliances are viewed as a portfolio with a focus on the

composition of alliance partners (e.g., Goerzen and Beamish, 2005; Lavie, 2007; Reuer and

Ragozzino, 2006; Stuart, 2000). Our study extends this emerging literature by establishing a

comprehensive construct of alliance portfolio diversity that incorporates functional diversity (the

range of activities for which the firm uses alliances), governance diversity (the variety of

structures with which the firm manages alliances) and partner diversity (the diversity of partners

with which the firm allies), and examines these constructs with respect to firm performance.

We underpin our work with resource-based theory where the firm is a bundle of heterogeneous

resources (Barney, 1991) and the dynamic capabilities framework where competitive advantage

draws from the firm’s ability to exploit as well as combine and re-combine resources that are

valuable, rare, and hard to imitate and substitute (Teece, Pisano and Schuen, 1997). In addition to

internal operations (i.e., the make) and external acquisitions and outsourcing (i.e., the buy)

alliance strategies are often an indispensable part of a firm’s overall corporate strategy where an

effective alliance portfolio can be a vital component for exploiting resources and exploring new

opportunities for attaining superior performance.

2

Page 4: ALLIANCE PORTFOLIO DIVERSITY AND FIRM ...sbafaculty.oakland.edu/Directory/jiang12/intellcont/Jiang... · Web viewCorporate-level three-year average of net profit margin (2000-2002

THEORY AND HYPOTHESES

Firms enter alliances for many reasons such as to pool complementary resources (Eisenhardt and

Schoonhoven, 1996), share costs and risks of undertaking expensive and highly uncertain

projects (Hagedoorn, 1993), and access or acquire needed resources, capabilities or knowledge

(Powell, Koput and Smith-Doerr, 1996). Studies found that greater alliance intensity is positively

associated with firm survival (Baum and Oliver, 1991), higher firm growth rates (Powell et al.,

1996), and higher levels of innovation (Hagedoorn and Schakenraad, 1994). However,

Hagedoorn and Schakenraad (1994) found no effect of technology alliances on profitability and

Stuart’s (2000) work shows not all alliances positively impact firm performance. We go beyond

recent work on network partner attributes to examine the diversity of alliance portfolio

composition and its relationship to firm performance.

Alliance portfolio diversity

We define alliance portfolio diversity as the degree of variance in partners, functional purposes,

and governance structures of the alliances. Prior studies have focused on partner diversity at the

dyad (e.g. Parkhe, 1991) or network level (e.g. Goerzen and Beamish, 2005). We contend that

alliance portfolio diversity must also consider variance in the functional scope and governance

structure of alliances. Thus, three key issues in alliance formation can be addressed: The first

issue is partner selection; with whom the firm allies. Our notion of alliance portfolio partner

diversity is similar to Goerzen and Beamish’s (2005) network diversity and refers to the degree

of variance in partners’ resources, capabilities, knowledge, and technological bases. The second

issue is the functional purpose of an alliance; what value-chain activities the firm performs in its

alliances. The third is governance structure; how the firm organizes and manages its alliances

using different organizing structures. Alliance portfolios vary in diversity along these three

3

Page 5: ALLIANCE PORTFOLIO DIVERSITY AND FIRM ...sbafaculty.oakland.edu/Directory/jiang12/intellcont/Jiang... · Web viewCorporate-level three-year average of net profit margin (2000-2002

dimensions and despite a large alliance literature there is a lack of studies examining all three of

these alliance diversity aspects in concert. In this study, we explore these three key dimensions

of portfolio diversity and their relationship to firm performance.

Partner diversity and firm performance

Partner selection is important since accessing or learning new skills from partner(s) is a prevalent

rationale for creating an alliance (Doz and Hamel, 1998; Hagedoorn, 1993). Prior studies

examined the relationship between partner characteristics and various firm performance

measures. For instance, Hagedoorn and Schakenraad (1994) found characteristics of alliance

partners are more important than the absolute number of alliances. Stuart (2000) found that firms

achieve higher innovation and growth rates when the alliance partners are larger and possess

more technological resources, while Goerzen and Beamish (2005) found that diversity in

Japanese firms’ foreign subsidiary networks in terms of industry and country background had a

U-shape relationship with corporate performance.

Parkhe (1991) distinguished between two types of partner diversity in his discussion of inter-

firm diversity. Type I diversity forms “the underlying strategic motivations for entering into

alliances”, in that partner differences can be complementary resources that “facilitate the

formulation, development, and collaborative effectiveness” of strategic alliances. Type II

diversity refers to differences in partner characteristics that might impede communication,

encumber knowledge transfer, and increase coordination difficulty (Parkhe, 1991:580). Over

time, Type II diversities go down and Type I diversity benefits increase (Parke, 1991). At the

portfolio level firms can reap net gain benefits from increasing partner diversity when the

benefits from Type I diversity outsize the costs resulting from managing Type II diversity.

4

Page 6: ALLIANCE PORTFOLIO DIVERSITY AND FIRM ...sbafaculty.oakland.edu/Directory/jiang12/intellcont/Jiang... · Web viewCorporate-level three-year average of net profit margin (2000-2002

Firms face trade-offs as they increase the diversity of their alliance portfolio. On one hand, a

highly diversified portfolio provides broadened search options, access to enriched resource

pools, and hence added value creation and capability development opportunities. On the other

hand, increased diversity can bring more complexity, the potential for more conflicts, and hence

increased coordination and managerial costs. Thus, the arguments for and against portfolio

diversity are often equally compelling. Following studies that consider curvilinear relationships

to reconcile two compelling contrary arguments (see for example, Golden and Zajac, 2001) we

punctuate these opposing arguments and explore the notion of nonlinear relationships between

our three partner diversity dimensions and firm performance.

Industry diversity. Alliances with firms from different industries can bring a host of benefits

and costs. Partners from the same industry are often competitors, who may bring the greatest

learning through imitation and greater absorptive capacity due to an overlap in backgrounds,

experiences, knowledge and technological bases (Cohen and Levinthal, 1990). On the other

hand, conflicts of interest exist and learning races (Doz and Hamel, 1998) can happen, increasing

monitoring and safeguarding costs. Partnering in upstream or downstream activities can offer

complementary resources and/or improve value chain coordination, while partners in unrelated

industries can facilitate entry into new markets (Kogut, 1988) or stimulate technological

innovations. However, such alliances are prone to resource misfits and/or lack of synergies,

causing alliances to underperform. Partners from different industries may also have very

different routines and processes that can make collaboration difficult. Thus, while greater partner

industry diversity may provide learning and resource access benefits, firms have to first

overcome two hurdles. First, different partners often bring myriad Type II diversities that can

impede alliance value creation (e.g., conflicts with competitors, lack of synergy with partners in

5

Page 7: ALLIANCE PORTFOLIO DIVERSITY AND FIRM ...sbafaculty.oakland.edu/Directory/jiang12/intellcont/Jiang... · Web viewCorporate-level three-year average of net profit margin (2000-2002

unrelated industries). Second, increased diversity increases alliance management complexity.

These downsides appear immediately as firms start increasing the degree of partner diversity.

However, as firms become more adept at dealing with such costs and as learning and resource

benefits accumulate, they may reach a minimum degree of diversity effectiveness and can expect

net gains surpassing this threshold. Goerzen and Beamish’s (2005) work, for instance, shows a

U-shaped relationship between partner diversity (measured by industry and national background)

and firm performance. We propose:

Hypothesis 1a: Greater alliance portfolio partner industry diversity is associated with firm performance that first decreases and then increases forming a U-shape.

National diversity. Alliances increasingly involve firms from different nation states. Cross-

border alliances can facilitate market entry (Glaister and Buckley, 1996), provide complementary

capabilities (Lane, Salk, and Lyles, 2001) and enhance different knowledge bases and learning

(Lubatkin, Florin, and Lane, 2001), but can pose a high potential for conflicts. For example,

Parkhe (1991, 1993) identified and tested five dimensions of diversity that might cause tension at

the alliance level: societal culture, national context, corporate culture, strategic direction, and

management policies/organization. Cross-border partners bring differences in political economic

systems, societal and cultural institutions, government policies, and national industry structures.

Such macro-level factors often result in differences in corporate culture, strategic direction, and

management practices where diversity in these various dimensions can cause conflicts and

increase alliance costs. Tung (1993), for instance, contrasted different communication patterns

between Americans and Japanese managers and offered a typology that punctuates the

difficulties in the interaction/acculturation process involving nationals from different countries.

At the portfolio level, allying with partners from different countries provides market and

resource access advantages. Yet, high national diversity can create excessive coordination and

6

Page 8: ALLIANCE PORTFOLIO DIVERSITY AND FIRM ...sbafaculty.oakland.edu/Directory/jiang12/intellcont/Jiang... · Web viewCorporate-level three-year average of net profit margin (2000-2002

integration costs due to the complexity in managing Type II diversities, thus firms must deal with

the downside of increased national diversity before they can reap net benefits. We propose:

Hypothesis 1b: Greater alliance portfolio partner national diversity is associated with firm performance that first decreases and then increases forming a U-shape.

Organizational Diversity. More global, dynamic, and competitive environments have forced

many firms to develop core competencies in fewer areas and consequently rely on external

sources for supplementary and complementary capabilities and knowledge (Santoro and

Chakrabarti, 2002). Alliances can be formed between large multi-divisional firms, between

public and private firms, and between for-profit businesses and not-for-profit organizations such

as universities and government agencies. Different types of organizations offer different pools of

resources and capabilities (Harrison, Hitt, Hoskisson, and Ireland, 2001). For example, large

public pharmaceutical firms often ally with small private biotech firms to tap into proprietary

technologies or specific technological expertise while smaller private biotechnology firms

benefit by gaining access to financial, marketing, and/or managerial resources and capabilities

(Santoro and McGill, 2005). Not-for-profit universities and government agencies can provide

basic and pre-competitive research that complements and supplements an industrial firm’s

shorter-term and more applied R&D efforts (Santoro & Chakrabarti, 2002). Firms allying with

organizations of different sizes, structures, and purposes increase their breadth of search,

learning capabilities, resource access, and reduce the threat of core rigidities. However, diverse

organizations tend to have different goals, decision-making processes, and systems that cause

communication and coordination difficulties, resulting in increased managerial costs. We

therefore propose:

Hypothesis 1c: Greater alliance portfolio partner organizational diversity is associated with firm performance that first decreases and then increases forming a U-shape.

7

Page 9: ALLIANCE PORTFOLIO DIVERSITY AND FIRM ...sbafaculty.oakland.edu/Directory/jiang12/intellcont/Jiang... · Web viewCorporate-level three-year average of net profit margin (2000-2002

Functional diversity and firm performance

Alliances can serve different functional purposes as firms can employ marketing, manufacturing,

and distribution alliances to broaden their market reach, enhance value creation, and further

exploit core competencies (Prahalad and Hamel, 1990). R&D alliances are prevalent in many

industrial sectors as firms take advantage of rapid technological advances while dealing with

soaring costs and risks of R&D (Hagedoorn, 1993). R&D involves exploration activities while

marketing, manufacturing, and distribution involve exploitation activities. Firms must balance

both, because exploitation relates to a firm’s current viability while exploration may critically

influence a firm’s future viability (March, 1991). As a firm increases the functional diversity of

its alliance portfolio it builds a more balanced portfolio that incorporates core and non-core

activities, gains access to supplementary and complementary assets, and expands its knowledge

base as well as market reach. This balanced approach can extend the firm’s range of value

creation activities, increase flexibility, and enhance overall firm performance. Following this

reasoning, we propose:

Hypothesis 2: Greater alliance portfolio functional diversity is positively associated with firm performance.

Governance diversity and firm performance

Alliances can be structured as non-equity or various equity-ownership arrangements where

different governance structures have different implications on level of commitment, degree of

integration, and learning (Kogut, 1988). Matching structure with the characteristics of each

cooperative venture is important to balance value creation and value appropriation (Lavie, 2007)

and reduce transaction costs (Santoro and McGill, 2005). However, it takes time and repeated

iterations to understand how to set up and manage a particular governance form since each

8

Page 10: ALLIANCE PORTFOLIO DIVERSITY AND FIRM ...sbafaculty.oakland.edu/Directory/jiang12/intellcont/Jiang... · Web viewCorporate-level three-year average of net profit margin (2000-2002

governance structure requires unique resource commitments, managerial attention, and

relationship building routines. Sampson (2005) found that repeated experience with a specific

governance structure can help the firm accumulate and institutionalize knowledge and skills

about a particular governance form. Once institutionalized, this knowledge becomes

organizational routines and operational protocols that can be readily applied to future alliances,

thereby reducing managerial costs. While attempting to match governance structures to the

variety of relationships in the portfolio can be thought of as a way to deal with transaction cost

issues, firms will be better served with a focused set of familiar structures rather than trying a

new governance form with each new alliance. Excessive experimenting with different

governance structures can significantly increase managerial complexity and lost opportunities for

institutional learning, yet provide minimal additional reduction in transaction cost hazards.

Following this reasoning, we propose:

Hypothesis 3: Greater alliance portfolio governance diversity is negatively associated with firm performance.

METHOD

We used the SDC Platinum Database to identify alliance portfolios for firms in the global

automobile industry (SIC 3714, 3711, 3751, 3713, 3715) during the period January 1985 to

December 2005. Performance data were obtained from Research Insight and Thompson Banker

One. We triangulated these data and obtained data sets for 138 multinational firms. A two-period

longitudinal panel for the period 1985-2005 with two time points (2000 and 2005) were created

to examine the cumulative effect of a firm’s alliance activities on a lagged measure of firm

performance. Year 2000 and 2005 were chosen for comparison since the number of alliances in

our sample frame was skewed toward the latter years of this twenty year period.

9

Page 11: ALLIANCE PORTFOLIO DIVERSITY AND FIRM ...sbafaculty.oakland.edu/Directory/jiang12/intellcont/Jiang... · Web viewCorporate-level three-year average of net profit margin (2000-2002

Dependent variable

Corporate-level three-year average of net profit margin (2000-2002 for time point one and 2005-

2007 for time point two) is our performance measure. Net profit margin has been used in a

number of previous studies to determine firm performance (e.g., Min and Wolfinbarger, 2005)

and is useful for comparing corporate performance in the same industry. A lagged three-year

average performance in each time period was used to reduce the likelihood of spurious results

due to one unusual performance year (Tanriverdi, 2006).

Independent and control variables

Alliance Portfolio Diversity is a multi-dimensional construct that includes partner, functional,

and governance diversity. We first coded each individual alliance into different categories. For

Industry Diversity, alliances were coded into 5 categories: “4” for an alliance formed with a

partner in the same 4-digit SIC code; “3” same 3-digit SIC code; “2” same 2-digit SIC code; “1”

same 1-digit SIC code, and “0” sharing no SIC code. For Organizational Diversity, two

measures were created to capture two, but related categories. Organizational Diversity I codes

alliances for ownership: “1” for same ownership (public-public, private-private); “0” different

ownership (public-private, public-government, private-government); Organizational Diversity II

codes alliances for organizational level: “1” same organization level (parent-parent, subsidiary-

subsidiary); “0” for different Org. level (parent-subsidiary). For Functional Diversity we coded

alliances into 4 categories where marketing is “1”, manufacturing “2”, R&D “3”, and Other “4”

(other activities that had insufficient numbers to justify individual coding). For Governance

Diversity we coded each alliance into 6 categories: “1”= non-equity, “2”= minor equity up to

20%, “3”= substantial share 21-49%, “4”=equal share 50%, “5”= major share 51-79% and

“6”=dominant share 80+%.

10

Page 12: ALLIANCE PORTFOLIO DIVERSITY AND FIRM ...sbafaculty.oakland.edu/Directory/jiang12/intellcont/Jiang... · Web viewCorporate-level three-year average of net profit margin (2000-2002

We then obtained our portfolio level diversity measures by using the Blau Index of Variability

(Blau, 1977). The Blau Index has been widely used in the group diversity literature to measure

heterogeneity of categorical variables where for any given diversity variable: D= 1 - pi2 where

D represents degree of diversity, p represents the proportion belonging to a given category, and i

is the number of different categories. The variables range from 0 (a perfectly homogeneous

group) to 1 (a perfectly heterogeneous group, with members spread evenly among all categories).

Since the size of each firm’s alliance portfolio was different (ranging from 2 to 354 alliances),

we divided the absolute diversity score by the highest possible Blau score based on the size of

the firm’s alliance portfolio. For National Diversity we coded a continuous variable, with “0” for

a portfolio with alliances with no foreign partners, “1” with partners from 1 foreign country, “2”

with partners from two foreign countries, and so on.

Our single industry controls for much variance. In addition, we included three control variables,

firm size (3 year average of total assets for the years 2005, 2006 and 2007 and for the years

2000, 2001, and 2002 in Hundred Million US $), portfolio size (the firm’s total number of

alliances at year 2000 and 2005), and portfolio size squared for a potential curvilinear effect.

Models and Results

We used Random-effects GLS Regression Analysis for hypotheses testing. Random-effects GLS

is considered more efficient and appropriate than fixed effect modeling if the data can pass the

Hausman’s Test. A Hausman test showed the coefficient estimates provided by the random

effects estimator were not significantly different to those offered by the fixed effects model

(Model 2 Χ², 8d.f. = 9.42, p = 0.31 and Model 3 Χ², 12d.f. = 11.3, p = 0.50) thus the more

efficient random effects model was used. Table 1 presents the descriptive statistics and

correlations, Table 2 our GLS Regression Analysis.

11

Page 13: ALLIANCE PORTFOLIO DIVERSITY AND FIRM ...sbafaculty.oakland.edu/Directory/jiang12/intellcont/Jiang... · Web viewCorporate-level three-year average of net profit margin (2000-2002

------Insert Tables 1 and 2 Here------

Model 1 included only the control variables, Model 2 added all our portfolio diversity variables

and Model 3 the quadratic terms for partner diversity. We mean centered the variables to avoid

multi-collinearity issues arising from adding quadratic terms. The control variables show

consistent results across all models and are consistent with previous studies. Model 3 shows the

root term for Industry Diversity is significant and negative (β = -2.8, p<0.05) while the squared

term is significant and positive (β = 7.35, p<0.05) indicating a U-shape relationship and

providing support for H1a. National Diversity is not significant thus H1b is not supported. Both

Organizational Diversity root terms are positive and significantly related to firm performance (β

= 6.69, p< 0.05, and β = 11.98, p<0.001 respectively). However since the root and square terms

for our Organizational Diversity measures are both positive and significant this indicates a J-

shape relationship rather than a U-shape relationship as we proposed in H1c. Model 3 shows

functional diversity is positively related to firm performance (β = 5.29, p<0.05) and governance

diversity is negatively related to firm performance (β = -2.72, p< 0.05) offering support for

hypotheses 2 and 3. We discuss our results and implications below.

DISCUSSION AND CONCLUSION

Overall, we found a complex relationship between alliance portfolio diversity and firm

performance. Mixed results were found regarding our three partner diversity constructs and firm

performance. Partner Industry Diversity has a U-shaped relationship with firm performance,

similar to Goerzen and Beamish’s (2005) findings in their study of Japanese firms while

Organizational Diversity showed a strong positive J-shaped relationship with firm performance,

suggesting benefits from collaborating with different types of partners (e.g., private and public,

for-profit and non-profit) outweigh the costs of managing these types of relationships. Functional

12

Page 14: ALLIANCE PORTFOLIO DIVERSITY AND FIRM ...sbafaculty.oakland.edu/Directory/jiang12/intellcont/Jiang... · Web viewCorporate-level three-year average of net profit margin (2000-2002

Diversity was found desirable as a diverse portfolio of value chain activities such as alliances in

R&D, manufacturing, and marketing brings both exploration and exploitation opportunities as

firms combine and leverage complimentary and supplementary resources and capabilities.

Governance diversity was found to be negatively associated with firm performance, reflecting

the importance of accumulating knowledge through repetition for managing and organizing

cooperative relationships.

Our results highlight the trade-offs in managing a diverse alliance portfolio between broadened

search, resource, and learning benefits and increased managerial complexity and costs as a firm’s

alliance portfolio diversity increases. Greater Organizational Diversity and Functional Diversity

can be beneficial while greater Governance Diversity detrimental to firm performance. We

believe organizational and functional diversity capture the learning and resource access benefits

accruing from collaborating with diverse organizations for a wide scope of functional purposes

while governance diversity points to the organizing difficulty and complexity of dealing with

myriad structures. Our diversity measures punctuate these results since a maximum diversity

score means a firm has an equal number of alliances in each category. In the case of industry

diversity, for example, the firm with a highly balanced alliance portfolio is collaborating with a

variety of partners in different sectors that add to their knowledge base. In the case of

governance diversity it means the firm employed an equal number of various types of ownership

structures where more is not necessarily better; too many governance forms are creating undue

complexity and deterring knowledge accumulation through a lack of systematic learning. These

findings illuminate the difficult tensions that must be balanced as firms reach out to different

partners in an attempt to maximize learning and at the same time, manage costs by not losing

focus on unfamiliar and under practiced governance forms.

13

Page 15: ALLIANCE PORTFOLIO DIVERSITY AND FIRM ...sbafaculty.oakland.edu/Directory/jiang12/intellcont/Jiang... · Web viewCorporate-level three-year average of net profit margin (2000-2002

One of our key contributions is advancing our multi-dimensional alliance portfolio diversity

construct that extends prior work focused solely on partner attributes. Future work could build

upon our functional and governance diversity measures to examine how widely firms use

alliances for various learning and value-chain activities and their linkage to different governance

forms. For practicing managers, our results highlight the strategic importance of developing a

comprehensive firm-level alliance strategy, adopting a portfolio perspective, installing an

alliance portfolio management process, and actively managing such a portfolio to develop

capabilities for improving firm performance (Hoffman, 2007).

Managers should consider collaborating with different organizations to access diverse pools of

resources and knowledge and use alliances for different value chain activities to enhance value

creation and flexibility since benefits appear to emanate from learning from and working with

partners on different activities. We caution managers not to be overly zealous in allying with

partners from too many different countries nor employing many different alliance governance

forms since they may better contain costs by using a framework of focused organizing structures.

Our data shows alliances are important to the global auto industry as our sample represents a

significant portion of the global automobile industry network. Since our one industry design

limits the generalizability of our findings, future research could investigate additional industries

such as telecommunications and electronics where alliances are also prevalent. Our results show

a non-significant relationship between national diversity and firm performance. We surmise the

auto industry’s widespread use of global alliances (as shown in our data and recent conversations

one of the authors had with auto industry executives) reduced the impact of national diversity.

Although beyond the scope of this current study, this could be examined in a future study. Future

research could also build upon our multi-dimensional alliance portfolio diversity construct to

14

Page 16: ALLIANCE PORTFOLIO DIVERSITY AND FIRM ...sbafaculty.oakland.edu/Directory/jiang12/intellcont/Jiang... · Web viewCorporate-level three-year average of net profit margin (2000-2002

examine the ways firms can optimize the learning and resource benefits while limiting the

complexity and coordination costs of managing a diverse alliance portfolio.

ACKNOWLEDGEMENTS

We thank the editor and two anonymous reviewers for their constructive feedback, Professor

Ravi Parameswaran and Nandu Nayar for their help with the project, and Martindale Center at

Lehigh University for their financial support.

REFERENCES

Barney J. 1991. Firm resources and sustained competitive advantage. Journal of Management 17 (1): 771-792.

Baum J, Oliver C. 1991. Institutional linkages and organizational mortality. Administrative Science Quarterly 36(2): 187-218.

Blau PM. 1977. Inequality and Heterogeneity. New York: The Free Press. Cohen WM, Levinthal DA. 1990. Absorptive capacity: A new perspective on learning and

innovation. Administrative Science Quarterly 35(1): 128-152.Doz YL, Hamel G. 1998. Alliance advantage: The art of creating value through partnering.

Boston, MA: Harvard Business School Press.Eisenhardt KM, Schoonhoven CB. 1996. Resource-based View of Strategic Alliance Formation:

Strategic and Social Effects in Entrepreneurial Firms. Organization Science 7(2):136-150.Glaister KW, Buckley PJ. 1996. Strategic motives for international alliances formation. Journal

of Management Studies 33(3): 301-332.Goerzen A, Beamish PW. 2005. The effect of alliance network diversity on multinational

enterprise performance. Strategic Management Journal 26(4): 333-354. Golden B, Zajac EJ. 2001. When will boards influence strategy? Inclination x power = strategic

change. Strategic Management Journal, 22: 1087-1111.Hagedoorn J. 1993. Understanding the rationale of strategic technology partnering:

Interorganizational modes of cooperation and sectoral differences. Strategic Management Journal, 14(5): 371-385.

Hagedoorn J, Schakenraad J. 1994. The effect of strategic technology alliances on company performance. Strategic Management Journal 15(4): 291–309.

15

Page 17: ALLIANCE PORTFOLIO DIVERSITY AND FIRM ...sbafaculty.oakland.edu/Directory/jiang12/intellcont/Jiang... · Web viewCorporate-level three-year average of net profit margin (2000-2002

Harrison JS, Hitt MA, Hoskisson RE, Ireland RD. 2001. Resource complementary in business combinations: extending the logic to organizational alliances. Journal of Management 27(6): 679-690.

Hoffman WH. 2007. Strategies for managing a portfolio of alliances. Strategic Management Journal 28: 827-856.

Kogut, B. 1988. Joint ventures: Theoretical and empirical perspectives. Strategic Management Journal, 9(4): 319-332.

Lane PJ, Salk JE, Lyles MA. 2001. Absorptive capacity, learning, and performance in international joint ventures. Strategic Management Journal 22(12): 1139-1161.

Lavie D. 2007. Alliance portfolios and firm performance: value creation and value appropriation in the U.S. software industry. Strategic Management Journal 28: 1187-1382.

Lubatkin M, Florin J, Lane PJ. 2001. Learning together and apart: a model of reciprocal interfirm learning. Human Relations 54(10): 1353-1378.

March JG. 1991. Exploration and exploitation in organizational learning. Organization Science 2(1): 71-87.

Min S, Wolfinbarger M. 2005. Market share, profit margin, and marketing efficiency of early movers, bricks and clicks, and specialists in e-commerce. Journal of Business Research 58(8): 1030.

Parkhe A. 1991. Interfirm diversity, organizational learning, and longevity. Journal of International Business Studies 22(4): 579-601.

Parkhe A. 1993. Partner nationality and the structure-performance relationship in strategic alliances. Organization Science 4(2): 301-324.

Powell W, Koput D, Smith-Doerr J. 1996. Interorganizational collaboration and the locus of innovation: Networks of learning in biotechnology. Administrative Science Quarterly 41(1): 116-145.

Prahalad CK, Hamel G. 1990. The core competence of the corporation. Harvard Business Review 68(3): 79-91.

Reuer JJ, Ragozzino R. 2006. Agency hazards and alliance portfolios. Strategic Management Journal 27(1): 27-43.

Sampson RC. 2005. Experience effects and collaborative returns in R&D alliances. Strategic Management Journal 26(11): 1009-1031.

Santoro M, Chakrabarti A. 2002. Firm size and technology centrality in industry-university interactions. Research Policy 31(7), 1163-1180.

Santoro M, McGill J. 2005. The effect of uncertainty and asset co-specialization on governance in biotechnology alliances. Strategic Management Journal 26(13): 1261-1269.

Stuart T E. 2000. Interorganizational alliances and the performance of firms: A study of growth and innovation rates in a high-technology industry. Strategic Management Journal 21(8): 791-811.

Tanriverdi H. 2006. Performance effects of information technology synergies in multibusiness firms. MIS Quarterly 30(1): 57-77.

Teece DJ, Pisano G, Schuen A. 1997. Dynamic capabilities and strategic management. Strategic Management Journal 18(7): 509-530.

Tung RL, 1993. Managing cross-National and intra-national diversity. Human Resource Management 32(4): 461-477.

16

Page 18: ALLIANCE PORTFOLIO DIVERSITY AND FIRM ...sbafaculty.oakland.edu/Directory/jiang12/intellcont/Jiang... · Web viewCorporate-level three-year average of net profit margin (2000-2002

Table 1. Descriptive statistics

Variables Mean S.D. 1 2 3 4 5 6 7 8

Net Profit

Margin

3.11 5.05

Firm Size 23.65 54.38 .07

Portfolio

Size

19.15 39.08 -.07 .53***

Industry

Diversity

0.61 0.29 -.21*** .11† .17**

National

Diversity

5.32 6.19 -.10† .38*** .27*** .23***

Organ.

Diversity I

0.30 0.20 -.15* .01 .24*** .28*** .24**

Organ.

Diversity II

0.34 0.17 .07 .16** .18** .21*** .21** .25***

Functional

Diversity

0.60 0.26 .08 .15** .09 -.07 -.07 .24*** .25***

Gov.

Diversity

0.36 0.26 -.12* .05 .14* .02 .18** .25*** .27*** .37***

N=276, †p<0.10, *p<0.05, **p<0.01, ***p<0.001

All variables pooled for descriptive purposes.

17

Page 19: ALLIANCE PORTFOLIO DIVERSITY AND FIRM ...sbafaculty.oakland.edu/Directory/jiang12/intellcont/Jiang... · Web viewCorporate-level three-year average of net profit margin (2000-2002

Table 2. Random-effects GLS regression results

Independent variables Model 1 Model 2 Model 3

Firm size .29 .10 .22

Portfolio size -.03 -.02 .05

Portfolio size squared .00 .00 .00

Industry diversity -5.02* -2.8*

National diversity .03 -.14

Organizational diversity I

Organizational diversity II

Functional diversity

-2.78*

2.13*

4.60*

6.69*

11.98***

5.29*

Governance diversity -3.45* -2.72*

Industry diversity squared

National diversity squared

Organizational diversity I squared

Organizational diversity II squared

Model F 4.17* 37.19***

7.35*

-.01

55.32***

49.10**

83.56***

R² within .00 .00 .02

R² between .02 .23 .40

R² overall .02 .16 .29

1. Regression Coefficients (β) are shown

2. †p<0.10, *p<0.05, **p<0.01, ***p<0.001

3. Number of observations=276; Number of groups (firms) = 138

18