trziste logisticki usluga

Upload: danijelstanojevic1

Post on 14-Apr-2018

228 views

Category:

Documents


0 download

TRANSCRIPT

  • 7/29/2019 Trziste logisticki usluga

    1/13

    This article was downloaded by: [Narodna Biblioteka Srbije]On: 08 April 2013, At: 04:55Publisher: Taylor & FrancisInforma Ltd Registered in England and Wales Registered Number: 1072954 Registeredoffice: Mortimer House, 37-41 Mortimer Street, London W1T 3JH, UK

    International Journal of Logistics

    Research and Applications: A Leading

    Journal of Supply Chain ManagementPublication details, including instructions for authors and

    subscription information:

    http://www.tandfonline.com/loi/cjol20

    Functional spin-offs in logistics service

    marketsJouni Juntunen a

    aDepartment of Marketing, University of Oulu, Oulu Business

    School, P.O. BOX 4600, Finland, 90014

    Version of record first published: 24 Mar 2010.

    To cite this article: Jouni Juntunen (2010): Functional spin-offs in logistics service markets,

    International Journal of Logistics Research and Applications: A Leading Journal of Supply Chain

    Management, 13:2, 121-132

    To link to this article: http://dx.doi.org/10.1080/13675560903562056

    PLEASE SCROLL DOWN FOR ARTICLE

    Full terms and conditions of use: http://www.tandfonline.com/page/terms-and-conditions

    This article may be used for research, teaching, and private study purposes. Anysubstantial or systematic reproduction, redistribution, reselling, loan, sub-licensing,

    systematic supply, or distribution in any form to anyone is expressly forbidden.

    The publisher does not give any warranty express or implied or make any representationthat the contents will be complete or accurate or up to date. The accuracy of anyinstructions, formulae, and drug doses should be independently verified with primarysources. The publisher shall not be liable for any loss, actions, claims, proceedings,demand, or costs or damages whatsoever or howsoever caused arising directly orindirectly in connection with or arising out of the use of this material.

    http://dx.doi.org/10.1080/13675560903562056http://www.tandfonline.com/page/terms-and-conditionshttp://www.tandfonline.com/page/terms-and-conditionshttp://dx.doi.org/10.1080/13675560903562056http://www.tandfonline.com/loi/cjol20
  • 7/29/2019 Trziste logisticki usluga

    2/13

    International Journal of Logistics: Research and Applications

    Vol. 13, No. 2, April 2010, 121132

    Functional spin-offs in logistics service markets

    Jouni Juntunen*

    Department of Marketing, University of Oulu, Oulu Business School, P.O. BOX 4600, Finland 90014

    (Received 20 February 2007; final version received 9 December 2009)

    The aim of this paper is to increase the understanding of logistics outsourcing decisions in a networkcontext. The concepts influencing the decision to outsource logistics activities are first identified, usingtheories in organisational economics, marketing and strategic management. A tentative model showingthe key concepts and their assumed relationships is developed and tested with empirical survey data fromindustrial companies in northern Finland. The estimations are made using structural equation modelling.Based on empirical analysis, a modified model is suggested which identifies two separate dimensions, ormodes, of the outsourcing concept. These outsourcing modes offer a useful tool for defining the classicconcept of functional spin-offs in logistics service markets. Moreover,the development paths of outsourcingrelationships between the shipper and service provider can be examined on the basis of the horizontal andvertical outsourcing modes proposed in the paper.

    Keywords: outsourcing; vertical integration; structural equation modelling; horizontal modulation;vertical modulation

    1. Introduction

    In todays competitive environment, companies must seek new, efficient ways to produce value for

    clients. For example, Greaver (1999) argues that organisations are questioning whether the tradi-

    tional paradigm of owning the factors of production is the best way to gain competitive advantage.

    The outsourcing concept, defined by Greaver as the act of transferring some of an organisations

    internal activities and decision rights to outside providers, is seen by many companies as a lucra-

    tive alternative to the traditional paradigm. Academic research in outsourcing has increased, but

    it has mostly been quite narrowly focussed on a particular theoretical orientation or empiricalsetting, such as information technology, transportation, etc. In logistics, outsourcing research typ-

    ically deals with the motives for outsourcing and the activities that are most frequently outsourced

    (the annual studies of third party logistics usage offer a good example, see e.g. Ashenbaum et al.

    (2005)). In marketing and distribution channel research, the focus is often on hypothesis testing,

    using transaction cost economics as a theoretical background (see e.g. Rindfleisch and Heide

    1997, Van Hoek 2000). A strategic view involves the definition of core competencies that should

    be kept in-house while outsourcing support functions and activities to external providers (e.g.

    Quinn and Hilmer 1994, Greaver 1999).

    *Email: [email protected]

    ISSN 1367-5567 print/ISSN 1469-848X online 2010 Taylor & FrancisDOI: 10.1080/13675560903562056http://www.informaworld.com

  • 7/29/2019 Trziste logisticki usluga

    3/13

    122 J. Juntunen

    The aim of this study is to increase understanding of logistics outsourcing decisions in a strategic

    network context. Drawing on multiple theoretical perspectives, a tentative conceptual model is

    developed andtested with Finnish survey data. The estimationis made using the structural equation

    modelling (SEM) technique. After further analysis of the data and supplementary theoretical

    contributions, a modified model is created that describes the rise of functional spin-offs (Mallen

    1973) in logistics service markets.

    The data were collected from northern Finnish companies in November 2005. The target group

    consisted of 587 companies and there were 161 acceptable responses, corresponding to a response

    rate of 27.4%. In northern Finland, industrial companies face special logistics challenges because

    of long distances and thin material flows. Therefore, outsourcing is a topical issue for industrial

    companies as well as for service providers in logistics. The manufacturers have to cope with high

    transport costs while the service providers try to consolidate volumes under tight competition.

    Thus, while the context of the study is geographically limited, it also offers an interesting setting

    for outsourcing research in logistics.

    2. Theoretical background

    Igor Ansoff, one of the pioneers of strategy, observed that a major decision related to organisational

    strategy culminates in the make or buy decision (Ansoff 1965). Today, when all competitive

    advantages are becoming temporary, it is even suggested that supply chain design is the most

    important competency of the firm (Fine 1998). Thus, a major question for a firm is what to make

    (vertical integration) and what to buy (outsourcing). From a theoretical point of view, the make or

    buy question is addressed in many areas of business economics, including the theory of the firmin microeconomics, transaction cost theory, agency theory, marketing and distribution channels

    research and strategic management. The concepts and assumptions are varied and little appears

    to have been done to create a synthesising doctrine for analysing outsourcing decisions.

    In this study an eclectic view is adopted by exploiting concepts from various theoretical back-

    grounds. This is important as relationships between customers and logistics service providers, like

    most other B-to-B relationships, are characterised by not only economic factors but also social

    exchange (Deepen 2007). Relying purely on the assumptions of microeconomics for studying the

    question of why there are firms, Barney and Ouchi (1986) suggest that firms should not exist at

    all. It was Coases (1937) fundamental insight that firms exist because it is costly to use the price

    system to coordinate economic activity. Coase argues that there is a trade-off between markets and

    the firms internal hierarchy. Williamson (1975) further studied alternative governance structures

    in transaction cost economics to determine the efficient boundaries of the firm.

    The fundamental difference between the transaction cost theory and agency theory is that

    while the former concentrates on market failures, the latter focuses on the relationships between

    markets and firms (Barney and Ouchi 1986). According to Hart (1995), the question is about the

    relationship between risk and gain; a frequent way to pose the problem is how to make the agents

    operate for the profit of the principal while trying to maximise their own utility, which may be

    in contrast with the principals benefit. Jensen and Mecklin (1976) argue that agent costs are the

    sum of the monitoring expenditures by the principal, the bonding expenditures by the agent and

    the residual loss.

    In early marketing literature, an important point was raised by Weld (1915) who argued thatmiddlemen can decrease the total costs of a distribution channel. Another theoretical view comes

    from the vertical marketing systems concept, which is defined as a set of forces, conditions and

    institutions associated with the sequential passage of a product or service through two or more

    markets (Bucklin and Stasch 1970). Mallen (1973) argues that a channel institution will delegate

  • 7/29/2019 Trziste logisticki usluga

    4/13

    International Journal of Logistics: Research and Applications 123

    those tasks that other firms can perform at a lower cost and will undertake only those tasks

    for which it has a cost advantage. According to Klein et al. (1990), when the volume of the

    product line increases, the probability of using a highly integrated channel increases in relation

    to the probability of using the market option. Also many product characteristics influence the

    principals decision to select the most suitable distribution channel (Aspinwall 1958).

    In strategic literature (Greaver 1999) outsourcing is seen as a way of solving problems due to

    incompetence, lack of capacity, financial pressures or technical failure. In this view, outsourcing

    is a tool for restructuring the supply chain. Schary and Skjott-Larsen (2001, p. 203), for instance,

    raise faster access to new markets as one of the reasons for third party logistics. Outsourcing also

    enables the investment of capital in core activities and may thereby increase production volume.

    Furthermore, adjusting the production volume becomes easier if the rate of outsourcing is high.

    Bengtsson and Berggren (2002) assert that the main reasons for the increase in outsourcing by

    Nokia and Ericsson are flexibility and improved reaction time for changes in demand for the

    products. In such a situation, the required quantity of production inputs can be acquired through

    a subcontractor without the necessity to hire more employees.

    3. Key concepts and tentative model

    In this section of the paper, a tentative model is developed for describing the key concepts and their

    relationships in the context of logistics service outsourcing. The model lays down those factors

    that influence the propensity to outsource logistics activities in the manufacturing organisations

    supply chain. From traditional make versus buy thinking, the model will be expanded towards a

    strategic network perspective (Thorelli 1986, Jarillo 1988) where outsourcing is seen as a meansof realising network benefits that increase the companys competitiveness.

    A central concept related to the outsourcing decision is resource specificity. This is an integrative

    concept that has its basis in transaction cost economics and the resource-based theory of the firm.

    According to Coase (1937), transaction costs have a positive correlation with vertical integration.

    The most important source of transaction costs is asset specificity (Williamson 1985, Rindfleisch

    and Heide 1997), which is closely linked with the strategic importance of the activity in question

    (Arnold 2000).When asset specificity and strategic importance are high, the degree of hierarchical

    coordination increases. By contrast, when the asset specificity and strategic importance are low, the

    degree of market coordination increases. In practice, there exist also various hybrid forms between

    hierarchical coordination (insourcing) and market coordination (outsourcing) which reflect the

    criticality of resources (Arnold 2000).

    The main reason why asset specificity increases transaction costs is the threat of ex post quasi-

    rents, which force the principal into complicated contracts with the agent(s). Klein et al. (1978)

    define quasi-rents as the value of an asset in its next best use to another renter. Especially under

    asymmetric information, quasi-rents may entail an ex post cost if the agent starts behaving oppor-

    tunistically after the relationship-specific investment has been made. On the other hand, quasi-rents

    also accrue to the principal through the deployment of non-tradeable assets that underlie the firms

    unique competences (Dierickx and Cool 1989). Thus, from an organisational economic point

    of view, resource specificity involves quasi-rents that reduce the propensity of the principal to

    outsource activities to external agents.

    The relationship is another important concept related to the outsourcing decision. In particular,when talking about third party logistics arrangements specifically tailored to each situation, the

    service providers and clients generally strive for long-term relationships with winwin benefits

    for both parties (Virum 1993). A positive association between relationship management efforts

    and outsourcing is observed by Knemeyer et al. (2003), especially when specific investments exist

  • 7/29/2019 Trziste logisticki usluga

    5/13

    124 J. Juntunen

    in the relationship. Similarly, Juga and Juntunen (2007) find that relationships create trust which

    is an important facilitator for outsourcing when specific investments are required in a logistics

    outsourcing situation.

    In any business relationship, the firm needs an adequate level of confidence in its partners

    cooperative behaviour. According to Das and Teng (1998), confidence stems from two main

    sources: trust and control. Trust encourages markets to work properly without adverse selection

    (Akerlof 1970). The importance of trust is also emphasised by Arrow (1972), who observes that

    every commercial transaction has an element of trust within it. In addition, the principals ability

    to control the agent should encourage the principal to cooperate. For instance, from a logistics

    service providers point of view, the carriers capability for monitoring drivers strongly affects

    make-or-buy decisions in the road freight context (Baker and Hubbart 2003).

    Outsourcing decisions are not self-contained but serve to improve the companys competi-

    tiveness in a strategic business network context. A strategic network is a governance mode that

    combines elements of the classic market and hierarchical control (Thorelli 1986). A network

    can be distinguished from a relationship-based clan which Jarillo (1988) sees as probably theclosest thing to what a Williamsonian hierarchy would be in real life (p. 34). For Jarillo (1988),

    there is always some degree of asset specificity built into the network relationships, and yet the

    contracting parties remain as independent organisations, with few or no points of contact along

    many of their dimensions (Figure 1).

    Based on the theoretical concepts and arguments above, a tentative model is developed with five

    hypotheses regarding the manufacturers propensity to outsource logistics in a strategic network

    context. First, it is proposed that resource-specificity, which is a composite concept based on

    transaction cost economics and the resource-based view of the firm, is negatively associated

    with the propensity to outsource logistics activities (H1). The second proposition is based on

    the assumption that that trust and control create confidence supporting good relationships, andthus a positive association exists between confidence and relationships (H2). Third, in a logistics

    outsourcing situation, existing relationships between the manufacturers (principals) and service

    providers (agents) are expected to show a positive impact on the propensity to outsource logistics

    activities (H3).

    The last two propositions link the outsourcing decision with Jarillos (1988) concept of the

    strategic network. It is expected that the outsourcing decisions are made to create network effects

    that strengthen the companys competitiveness. Network effects (or network economies) are based

    on the positive externalities that specialised actors can achieve through economies of scale and

    scope when acting together. Therefore, a proposition is made that outsourcing is positively asso-

    ciated with network economies for the manufacturing organisation (H4). However, the network

    model is essentially based on the facilitating influence of business relationships. Therefore, it is

    assumed that the relationships also have a positive impact on network economies (H5), in addi-

    tion to the impact they have on the discrete outsourcing decision. The tentative model with the

    proposed hypotheses is shown in Figure 2.

    In all business relationships, both relational and transactional aspects exist in the various stages

    of the relationship. A relational orientation is normally developed as the relationship matures

    Figure 1. Four modes of organising economic activity (Jarillo 1988).

  • 7/29/2019 Trziste logisticki usluga

    6/13

    International Journal of Logistics: Research and Applications 125

    Figure 2. Outsourcing decisions in a strategic network context.

    and personal contacts become closer. However, the opposite tendency may also occur in some

    circumstances (Pillai and Sharma 2003). Similarly, the governance mechanism of an outsourc-

    ing relationship may change from the dyadic approach towards multilateral network logic as

    the relationship matures (Halldorsson and Skjott-Larsen 2006). In this paper, it is assumed that

    transactional and relational dimensions complement each other as the antecedents for outsourcing

    decisions. Moreover, it is proposed that relationships and outsourcing together form the basis for

    network economies that strengthen the companys competitiveness.

    4. Empirical analysis

    This section presents an empirical test of the model using SEM (Jreskog et al. 2000). The

    operational measures are first presented and the tentative model is tested with survey data from

    Finnish companies that buy logistics services. Based on the modification indexes of the Lisrel

    software, amendments are made and the final model is then presented with interpretations.

    4.1. Data description and estimation method

    The data were collected in November 2005 in connection with a regional logistics strategy project

    (Juntunen 2006). The target group consisted of northern Finnish companies that consume logistics

    services (e.g. mining, manufacturing, maintenance and construction). Measured by turnover, the

    600 largest companies in the region were selected for the sample. All companies with fewer than

    five employees were excluded. The resulting sample included some companies twice because

    they had several offices in the region. After removing these duplicates, the final sample consisted

    of 587 companies. The contact addresses were acquired from Itella Oyjs (www.itella.fi) database

    and the survey was administered via the Internet, using the Webropol survey application. The

    questionnaire was pilot tested by the steering group of the Northern Finnish logistics strategy

    project. The questions in the questionnaire were based on a seven-point Likert scale.

    An e-mail was sent to the companies with a link to the Internet questionnaire as well as back-

    ground information about the project and the researchers contact details. After a weeks response

    time, the companies were contacted by telephone to remind them about the survey and ask for

    responses. In total 161 acceptable responses were received, corresponding to a 27.4% response

    rate. This can be considered very satisfactory if compared with the declining trend that has been

    observed in logistics surveys recently (e.g. Larson 2005).Non-response bias was studied by comparing different response waves (see e.g. Lambert and

    Harrington 1990). The first wave included companies that responded after the original e-mail

    request (6.0%). The second wave consisted of companies that responded after the telephone

    reminder (21.4%). A randomised one-way analysis of variance was used to test whether any

  • 7/29/2019 Trziste logisticki usluga

    7/13

    126 J. Juntunen

    differences existed between the groups. There were no statistically significant differences (using

    the criterion of p > 0.05) between the two groups for any of the variables used in this study.

    Therefore, it may be assumed that non-response bias is not a problem in this study.

    The respondents had completed the questionnaires thoroughly and the overall filling rate of the

    questions was 98.2%. Missing data were completed using the expectation maximisation function

    of the SPSS statistical package. The estimation was made by using the SEM technique with the

    Lisrel software (Jreskog and Srbom 1993a, Jreskog et al. 2000, Du Toit and Du Toit 2001).

    The estimates were calculated using the maximum likelihood method based on the covariance

    matrix from variables with a normal distribution. The normality of the variables was examined

    using the Prelis 2 software (Jreskog and Srbom 1993b).

    4.2. Data analysis

    Based on the tentative model above, there were five latent variables which were measured with

    the Likert-scale statements outlined in Table 1.

    Using these operational measures, the tentative model was tested with the SEM technique. Two

    of the hypothesised relationships in this original model were not statistically significant. However,

    as the test values for statistical fit of the entire model were quite promising (chi-square 47.65,

    df. 29, p-value 0.015, RMSEA 0.063), a decision was made to modify the model by removing a

    problematic association between the relationship and outsourcing factors. In the modified model

    (Figure 3) all the remaining relationships were statistically significant. However, the statistical

    fit of the entire model (chi-square 49.23, df. 30, p-value 0.015, RMSEA 0.06) was still slightly

    below the acceptable level.

    In order to develop the model further, an exploratory analysis was made to examine how the

    latent variables associate with different types of outsourcing. The factor was therefore dividedinto two separate dimensions. On the one hand, outsourcing involves a horizontal dimension,

    characterised by competitive relationships with multiple service providers. On the other hand,

    it also involves a vertical dimension that is based on deep co-operation with selected service

    provider(s). Obviously, the horizontal mode of outsourcing is closely related with traditional spot

    market transactions while the vertical mode is related with long-term partnerships. The new factors

    and their operational measures are presented in Table 2.

    With these amendments, the model gave a mediocre fit (chi-square 52.89, df. 38, p-value 0.055,

    RMSEA 0.049). Although this model is statistically acceptable, the modification indexes of the

    LISREL software reported high error correlations between the measures Deeper and Routines.

    Table 1. Operational measures of the latent variables.

    Label Latent variable Label Operational measure

    ResSpe Resource specificity AssetSpe The resources allocated for our logistics providers are only suitedfor the present relationship

    CoreComp Controlling logistics is a part of our firms core competence

    Relation Relationships Routines We have good routines with our logistics partners for dealing withproblem situations

    PerRelat We have good personal relationships with our logistics partnersConfiden Confidence Control Open information exchange works well with our logistics partners

    Trust Our logistics partners would never behave deceitfully

    NetEco Network economies Contract We can use standardised contracts with our logistics partnersCompetit We strengthen our competitiveness by outsourcing

    Outsourc Outsourcing Deeper With high probability we will outsource more activities to our mainlogistics provider

    Wider With high probability we will outsource more activities to newlogistics providers

  • 7/29/2019 Trziste logisticki usluga

    8/13

    International Journal of Logistics: Research and Applications 127

    Figure 3. The modified model (standardised solution).

    Table 2. Operational measures of vertical and horizontal outsourcing.

    Label Latent variable Label Operational measure

    Hori Horizontal outsourcing Wider With high probability we will outsource more functions to newlogistics providers

    Change With high probability we will change our main logistics provider

    Vert Vertical outsourcing Deeper With high probability we will outsource more activities to our mainlogistics provider

    Figure 4. Final model with two outsourcing modes (standardised solution).

    Thus this correlation was set to be free in the final model (Figure 4). This did not change the model

    as a whole, but improved the fit indexes to a very good level (Table 3).

    The chi-square test shows an acceptable fit of the model to the data, the minimum acceptable

    p-value normally being 0.05. According to Browne and Cudeck (1993), an RMSEA value below0.05 indicates a close fit of the model. Jaccard and Wan (1996) argue that the models CFI and

    GFI values should be above 0.90. The value of the normed chi-square should be between 1.0 and

    2.0. Therefore, based on all these test values, the model can be considered acceptable. Further, all

    relationships in the model are statistically significant.

  • 7/29/2019 Trziste logisticki usluga

    9/13

    128 J. Juntunen

    Table 3. Fit indexes of the final model.

    Test Value p-Value

    Chi-square (df) 45.38(37) 0.162

    RMSEA 0.038 Comparative fit index (CFI) 0.98

    Goodness of fit index (GFI) 0.95

    SRMR 0.069 Normed chi-square 1.337

    According to Bollen (1989), the validity of the measures is equal to the factor loadings. Even

    though the final model provides a very good statistical fit, the loadings of the measures AssetSpe

    and Contract are not good. Because the factors have only two measures at the maximum, they

    are unidentified without full structure and it is therefore impossible to perform factor analyses of

    individual latent variables. This also weakens the usability of traditional test values such as theaverage variance extracted (AVE) and, therefore, the results should be evaluated primarily on the

    basis of the fit indexes of the full model.

    4.3. Implications

    In the final model, the resource specificity (ResSpe) factor associates negatively withthe horizontal

    outsourcing. This result supports proposition H1 with the limitation that the vertical mode of

    outsourcing is separated from the original outsourcing factor. It should be noted that the error

    terms of the measures for resource specificity are quite high. The resource specificity factorsAVE value is 0.29 and construct reliability is 0.27. On the other hand, there is theoretical support

    (Arnold 2000) for the interconnection between the two measures.

    Despite a relatively low factor loading of the trust variable, the confidence (Confiden) factors

    validity is satisfactory. The AVE value is 0.44 and construct reliability is 0.56. Furthermore, there

    are theoretical arguments (Das and Teng 1998) for linking trust and control as dimensions of

    confidence. The factor associates positively with relationships, as expected in H2.

    The validity of the relationship (Relation) factor is good, theAVE value being 0.60 and construct

    reliability 0.86. In the tentative model, the relationships factor is expected to associate positively

    with outsourcing (H3). Surprisingly, the data did not support this association and the proposition

    was rejected. However, there is an indirect association between the relationships and outsourcing

    via the network economies factor.

    By splitting the outsourcing (Outsourc) factor into horizontal and vertical modes of outsourcing,

    a reasonable validity is achieved for both factors. TheAVE value for horizontal outsourcing (Hori)

    is 0.58 and the construct reliability is 0.80. The construct reliability for vertical outsourcing (Vert)

    is high (0.95), due to a very low error term. However, the AVE value is low (0.49) because there

    is only one measure describing the vertical outsourcing factor.

    The network economies (NetEco) factor shows a reasonable validity (AVE 0.47 and construct

    reliability 0.60). The factor is associated with relationships and vertical outsourcing, and indirectly

    with horizontal outsourcing. Thus, the propositions H4 and H5 are supported with a minor

    modification. The change could mean that companies begin outsourcing by buying services on

    spot markets and develop partnerships with selected service providers later on as experiencegrows.

    In the final model, the modification indexes showed a correlation of error terms between the

    Routines and the Deeper measures. This could be explained by the development of working

    routines with the maturing business relationship. Good routines reduce co-ordination costs, which

  • 7/29/2019 Trziste logisticki usluga

    10/13

    International Journal of Logistics: Research and Applications 129

    is also consistent with the idea of network economies that are themselves attributed to increasing

    standardisation by means of contracts in the outsourcing relationship.

    5. Discussion

    Following the strategic network concept by Thorelli (1986) and Jarillo (1988), it maybe reasonable

    to consider two alternative dimensions of outsourcing. On the one hand, the vertical mode of

    outsourcing means concentrating on transaction costs. In this mode, the principal and the agent

    have deep and long-term co-operation, which lowers transaction costs between the partners. On the

    other hand, the horizontal mode means concentrating on input prices. In this mode, the principal

    has several agents who compete against each other. In both cases the principal influences and

    controls the outsourced functions and there are no true markets. When multiple firms outsource

    their functions, network economies start to develop and the principals influence on individualagents is reduced.

    Thorelli (1986) and Jarillo (1988) split external costs into two different categories: the price

    of input and transaction costs. Competition in the market can lower the input price, but using

    multiple suppliers increases search, contract and controlling costs. On the other hand, one can

    lower transaction costs by long-term contracts, but the price can become higher than under tight

    competition. According to Jarillo (1988), establishing an efficient network implies the ability to

    reduce transaction costs, for it is precisely those costs that also lead firms to integrate. Hence, the

    strategic network can take advantage of economies in scale with low transaction costs. These two

    types of cost are also relevant for understanding the different modes of outsourcing described in

    this study.

    The vertical mode of outsourcing creates efficiency in network governance and decreasing

    costs in the long term. However, the vertical outsourcing mode may involve higher short-term

    costs. The horizontal mode, by contrast, enables short-term cost savings because of tight bidding

    games, but does not encourage agents to invest in long-term relationship development such as

    research and development, quality, information systems and so on. The degree to which the

    Figure 5. Different modes of outsourcing underlying functional spin-offs.

  • 7/29/2019 Trziste logisticki usluga

    11/13

    130 J. Juntunen

    company deploys the vertical and horizontal modes of outsourcing could be titled vertical and

    horizontal modulation, respectively (Figure 5). The option where both vertical and horizontal

    modulation is high is where network economies are accomplished. Using a well-known concept

    from economic literature (Stigler 1951, Mallen 1973), this special mode of outsourcing could be

    named functional spin-offs.

    Based on the empirical findings of this study, it seems that the path to network economies in

    logistics starts from horizontal outsourcing and advances through increasing vertical modulation

    to functional spin-offs. In practice, this could mean that the principal first learns how to buy

    logistics services from markets and then moves on to partnerships to reduce transaction costs.

    A functional spin-off occurs as a combination of the vertical and horizontal modes when the

    principal has enough competence to set out total logistics solutions for the competition and when

    the markets are fully developed to offer such solutions.

    6. Conclusions

    Logistics outsourcing is a complex phenomenon involving concepts and models from multiple

    theoretical backgrounds. In this paper, an essentially eclectic approach is chosen to study the

    antecedents of outsourcing decisions and their outcomes in a network context. The analysis shows

    that both transactional and relational orientations are relevant for outsourcing decisions in business

    networks. However, the findings also indicate a need to look at different modes of outsourcing

    that may increase the understanding of outsourcing strategies in logistics and the dynamics of

    outsourcing relationships.

    On the one hand, it seems that a horizontal mode of outsourcing can be distinguished, involvingmultiple service providers that compete for contracts on spot markets. On the other hand, a vertical

    mode of outsourcing involves close partnerships with selected service providers on a long-term

    basis. The extent to which these modes are present in an outsourcing relationship might be called

    horizontal and vertical modulation, respectively. A fully developed outsourcing relationship, with

    a high level of horizontal and vertical modulation, entails a functional spin-off that can serve as

    a source of substantial network economies to the partners.

    Based on the empirical findings, it seems that the development of outsourcing relationships

    goes from the horizontal mode to the vertical mode and finally to functional spin-offs. This can

    be compared with the popular view of the evolution of logistics service provision from in-house

    logistics through the purchasing of discrete logistics services and on to 3PL (long-term third-

    party outsourcing arrangements) and 4PL (logistics integrator arrangements). Theoretically, the

    distinction of different outsourcing modes can shed new light on the definition and circumstances

    in which these outsourcing arrangements are likely to be found.

    From a managerial point of view, the results can help shippers and service providers to create

    a common understanding about the terms, goals and challenges when initiating and developing

    outsourcing relationships. While long-term outsourcing partnerships can be beneficial, there may

    be additional network benefits to gain for the partners if the contracts were reframed on the

    basis of vertical as well as horizontal modes of outsourcing. However, this does not mean that

    all outsourcing relationships are destined to move towards the option of functional spin-offs.

    Instead, the organisational and environmental circumstances should be carefully evaluated and

    the outsourcing relationships designed accordingly.In this study, the survey population was restricted to northern Finnish companies which may

    have affected the generalisability of the results. While the industry spectrum is fairly similar to

    Finnish industry in general, there are some special conditions in the region that may affect logistics

    outsourcing decisions and relationships long distances and thin material flows, for instance.

  • 7/29/2019 Trziste logisticki usluga

    12/13

    International Journal of Logistics: Research and Applications 131

    Therefore, broader empirical research is needed to corroborate the findings. Further research is

    also needed for developing the measures of the key concepts and thereby improving the validity of

    the research. From a theoretical point of view, the concept of network economies opens interesting

    research opportunities in a service outsourcing context. Organisational economics, and especially

    transaction cost analysis, is widely used in outsourcing research, but there seems to be few links

    to the concept of network economies. Finally, there are a number of other theoretical concepts

    in inter-organisational research, such as power, dependence, conflict, etc., not accounted for in

    this study. The extension of the model toward these behavioural concepts offers another possible

    direction for future research.

    References

    Akerlof, G.A., 1970. The market for Lemons: quality uncertainty and the market mechanism. Quarterly Journal ofEconomics, 84 (3), 488500.Ansoff, H.I., 1965. Corporate strategy. New York: McGraw-Hill.Arnold, U., 2000. New dimensions of outsourcing: a combination of transaction cost economics and the core competencies

    concept. European Journal of Purchasing and Supply Management, 6 (1), 2329.Arrow, K.J., 1972. Gifts and exchanges. Philosophy and Public Affairs, 1 (4), 343362.Ashenbaum, B., Maltz,A., and Rabinovich,E., 2005. Studies of trends in third-party logistics usage: whatcan we conclude?

    Transportation Journal, 44 (3), 3950.Aspinwall, L., 1958. The characteristicsof goodand parallelsystems theories.In: E. Kelleyand W. Lazer, eds.Management

    marketing. Homewood, IL: Irwin.Baker, G.B. and Hubbart, T.N., 2003. Make versus buy in trucking: asset ownership, job design, and information.

    American Economic Review, 93 (3), 551572.Barney, J.B. and Ouchi, W.G., eds., 1986. Organizational economics. San Francisco, CA: Jossey-Bass Inc. Publishers.Bengtsson, L. and Berggren, C.,2002. Horizontally integrated or vertically divided?A comparisonof outsourcing strategies

    at Ericsson and Nokia. Working paper, Linkping universitet.Bollen, K.A., 1989. Structural equations with latent variables. New York: Wiley.Browne, M.W. and Cudeck, R., 1993. Alternative ways of assessing model of fit. In: K. Bollen and J.S. Long, eds., Testing

    structural equation models. Palm Springs, CA: Sage Publications Inc.Bucklin, L.P. and Stasch, S.F., 1970. Problems in the study of vertical marketing systems. In: L.P. Bucklin, ed. Vertical

    marketing systems. Glenview, IL: Scott, Foreman and Company.Coase, R.H., 1937. The nature of the firm. Economica, 4 (16), 386405.Das, T.K. and Teng, B-S., 1998. Between trust and control: developing confidence in partner cooperation in alliances.

    Academy of Management Review, 23 (3), 491512.Deepen, J.M., 2007. Logistics outsourcing relationships. New York: PhysicaVerlag Heidelberg.Dierickx, I. and Cool, K., 1989. Asset stock accumulation and sustainability of competitive advantage. Management

    Science, 35 (12), 15041513.Du Toit, M. and Du Toit, S., 2001. Interactive LISREL: users guide. Lincolnwood, IL: 2001 SSI, Inc.Fine, C.H., 1998. Clockspeed: winning industry control in the age of temporary advantages. Cambridge: Basic Books.

    Greaver, M.F., 1999. Strategic outsourcing. New York: AMA Publications.Halldorsson, A. and Skjott-Larsen, T., 2006. Dynamics of relationship governance in TPL arrangements a dyadic

    perspective. International Journal of Physical Distribution and Logistics Management, 36 (7), 490506.Hart, O.D., 1995. Firms, contracts, and financial structures. Oxford: Clarendon Press.Jaccard,J. andWan, C.K., 1996.Lisrelapproaches to interaction effect in multiple regression.California: Sage Publications

    Inc.Jarillo, C.J., 1988. On strategic networks. Strategic Management Journal, 9 (1), 3141.Jensen, M.C. and Mecklin, W.H., 1976. Theory of the firm: managerial behaviour, agency costs, and ownership structure.

    Journal of Financial Economics, 3 (4), 305360.Juga, J. and Juntunen, J., 2007. Trust, control and confidence in logistics outsourcing decisions. In: A. Halldorsson and

    G. Stefansson, eds. Proceedings of the 19th annual nofoma conference, 79 June, Reykjavik, 597608.Juntunen, J., 2006. Pohjois-Suomen logistisen kilpailukyvyn vahvistaminen: kyselytutkimus(Logistics competitiveness

    of Northern Finland: a survey study) [online]. Council of Oulu Region. Available from: http://www.pohjois-pohjanmaa.fi/file.php?678 [Accessed 23 April 2008].

    Jreskog, K.G. and Srbom, D., 1993a. LISREL 8: structural equation modeling with the SIMPLIS command language.Lincolnwood, IL: SSI, Inc.

    Jreskog, K.G. and Srbom, D., 1993b. PRELIS 2:users reference guide. Lincolnwood, IL: SSI, Inc.Jreskog, K.G., et al., 2000. LISREL 8: new statistical features. Lincolnwood, IL: SSI, Inc.Klein, B., Crawford, R.G., andAlchian,A.A., 1978. Vertical integration, appropriable rents and the competitive contracting

    process. Journal of Law and Economics, 21, 297326.

  • 7/29/2019 Trziste logisticki usluga

    13/13

    132 J. Juntunen

    Klein, S., Frazier, G.L., and Roth, V.J., 1990. A transaction cost analysis model of channel integration in internationalmarkets. Journal of Marketing Research, 27 (2), 196208.

    Knemeyer, M.A., Corsi, T.M., and Murphy, P.R., 2003. Logistics outsourcing relationships: customer perspectives.Journalof Business Logistics, 24 (1), 77109.

    Lambert, D.M. and Harrington, T.C., 1990. Measuring nonresponse bias in customer service mail surveys. Journal of

    Business Logistics, 11 (2), 525.Larson, P.D., 2005. A note on mail surveys and response rates in logistics research. Journal of Business Logistics, 26 (2),

    211222.Mallen, B., 1973. Functional spin-off: a key to anticipating change in distribution structure. Journal of Marketing, 37 (3),

    1825.Pillai, G.K. and Sharma, A., 2003. Mature relationships: why does relational orientation turn into transaction orientation?

    Industrial Marketing Management, 32 (8), 643651.Quinn, J.B. and Hilmer, F.G., 1994. Strategic outsourcing. Sloan Management Review, 35 (4), 4355.Rindfleisch, A. and Heide, J.B., 1997. Transaction cost analysis: past, present, and future applications. Journal of

    Marketing, 61 (4), 3054.Schary, P.B. and Skjott-Larsen, T., 2001. Managing the global supply chain. 2nd ed. Copenhagen, Denmark: Copenhagen

    Business School Press.Stigler, J.G., 1951. The division of labour is limited by the extent of the market. Journal of Political Economy, 59 (3),

    185193.Thorelli, H.B., 1986. Networks: between markets and hierarchies. Strategic Management Journal, 7 (1), 3751.Van Hoek, R.I., 2000. The purchasing and control of supplementary third-party logistics services.Journal of Supply Chain

    Management, 36 (4), 1426.Virum, H., 1993. Third party logistics development in Europe. Logistics and Transportation Review, 29 (4), 355361.Weld, L.D.H., 1915. Market distribution. American Economic Review, 5 (1), 125139.Williamson, O.E., 1975. Markets and hierarchies: analysis and antitrust implications. New York: Free Press.Williamson, O.E., 1985. The economic institutions of capitalism. New York: Free Press.