istituto di politiche pubbliche e scelte collettive –...

30
ISSN: 2038-7296 POLIS Working Papers [Online] Istituto di Politiche Pubbliche e Scelte Collettive – POLIS Institute of Public Policy and Public Choice – POLIS POLIS Working Papers n. 234 March 2016 Is Italy a Federal or even a Quasi-Federal State? Albert Breton and Angela Fraschini UNIVERSITA’ DEL PIEMONTE ORIENTALE “Amedeo AvogadroALESSANDRIA Periodico mensile on-line "POLIS Working Papers" - Iscrizione n.591 del 12/05/2006 - Tribunale di Alessandria

Upload: phungkhanh

Post on 16-Mar-2018

221 views

Category:

Documents


3 download

TRANSCRIPT

ISSN: 2038-7296POLIS Working Papers

[Online]

Istituto di Politiche Pubbliche e Scelte Collettive – POLISInstitute of Public Policy and Public Choice – POLIS

POLIS Working Papers n. 234

March 2016

Is Italy a Federalor even a Quasi-Federal State?

Albert Breton and Angela Fraschini

UNIVERSITA’ DEL PIEMONTE ORIENTALE “Amedeo Avogadro” ALESSANDRIA

Periodico mensile on-line "POLIS Working Papers" - Iscrizione n.591 del 12/05/2006 - Tribunale di Alessandria

The members of the POLIS Institute are proud to publish one of the last paper by

Albert Breton, coauthored with Angela Fraschini.

Albert   Breton   passed   away   on   February   13,   2016.   Born   in   June   1929,   he   was

Emeritus Professor of Economics at the University of Toronto, Canada. He and his

work were also  well  known and appreciated   in  Italy,  where  he  frequently  was a

visiting scholar. 

Albert Breton received his PhD in Economics from Columbia University, New York.

He   taught   among   others   at   Montréal   University,   Carleton   University,   Université

Catholique   de   Louvain,   London   School   of   Economics,   Harvard   University,

Università   di  Perugia,  Université   de  Paris   I   (Panthéon­Sorbonne)   and   Institut   de

Sciences Politiques de Paris. He carried out research for the Institute for Social and

Economic Change (Bangalore, India). 

He authored over 130 books and papers on (fiscal) federalism, constitutional political

economy, economic theory and political science.

He was special counselor to the Prime Minister Pierre Trudeau for ten years in the

1970’s,   vice   president   of  Applebaum­Hébert   Federal   Cultural   Policy   Review

Committee  (1979 ­1982) and member of the  MacDonald Royal Commission on the

Economic Union and Development Prospects for Canada (1982 ­ 1985).

Member of the board of directors of the National Theatre School of Canada, he was

an Officer of the Order of Canada (since 1984), member of the Royal Society of

Canada (since 1979), Honoris Causa Laureate at University of Manitoba and past

president of the Canadian Economic Association. A book in his honor was published

in 2000 by Cambridge University Press.

Albert Breton was a corresponding member of the POLIS Institute and coauthored

papers with some of us. We have all lost a great colleague and a friend.

Is Italy a Federal or even a Quasi-Federal State?

Albert Breton – University of Toronto (Canada)

Angela Fraschini – Università del Piemonte Orientale “A. Avogadro” (Italy)

Abstract Constitutional adjustments over recent decades, but especially the important

constitutional reforms of 2001, have led to significant increases in the degree of decentralization

of the Italian Republic, at least formally. These changes have induced a number of knowledgeable

observers to conclude that if Italy was not a federal state, it was on its way to becoming one. We

consider the same question by making use of a widely accepted model of the assignment of

powers. We make use of the "reduced form" of an up-to-date version of the Breton-Scott

organizational cost model – a reduced form which allows us to concentrate on coordination

activities and costs. To understand coordination, we must acknowledge that powers are

Edgeworth complements – modification of one power has repercussion throughout the

constitutional system. In all decentralized states, coordination activities are vested in institutional

bodies. In Italy, they are vested in a System of Conferences. We describe the legislative

framework of that System and, following that, we document how it has operated in practice. We

come to the conclusion that Italy does not appear be on its way to becoming a federal state.

Keywords Government - Federal State – Federalism - Intergovernmental Relations

JEL Classification H70 - H77 - H79 January 2014 --------------------

2

1 Introduction

In the tripartite classification of governmental systems as either confederal, federal, or

unitary, Italy is generally taken to be a unitary state. It is, however, a governmental

system that has seen a continuously increasing degree of decentralization, particularly

since the 1970s.1 In particular, following the important constitutional reform of 2001, all

levels of government have been formally granted equal constitutional status and, as a

consequence, the central government is no longer in a position of formal hierarchical

supremacy vis-à-vis the other jurisdictional levels.2 Moreover, in the amended Article

117 of the Constitution there are now two lists of powers: one enumerating the powers

assigned to the central government, and another the powers that are concurrent;

furthermore, all the powers that are not listed are now assigned to the regions, whereas in

the original pre-2001 Article 117, the powers of the regions were enumerated and all

other powers were assigned to the central authority. Finally, in matters included in the list

of concurrent powers, both the central and regional governments can legislate, but the

central government can only set general principles, not the operational details which it is

the prerogative of the regions to formulate. All of this can be and has been adduced as

evidence of genuine (not only formal) increased decentralization.

The changes have led some observers to suggest that Italy should be considered a

de facto quasi-federal or possibly even a federal state. For example, Francesco Palermo

and Jens Woelk (2007, 18) have expressed the view that "at the moment, Italy can best be 1 For a brief history of decentralization in Italy, see, for example, Palermo and Wilson (2013), Pola (2008), and Breton and Fraschini (2003, 65-69). 2 The words formal and formally have meanings that vary with the context. The precise meaning we give to the two words will become apparent in Section 3, especially in subsection 3.3.

3

described as a devolutionary asymmetric federal system in the making. The term

devolutionary is appropriate because powers have been transferred from the national

government to the regions; [and the term] asymmetric reflects [the fact] that there are two

types of regions and the implementation of federalism differs from region to region …"

Palermo and Woelk know that Italy is not a federal state, as the title of their paper makes

clear, but it is a state that one can expect will become a federal state. Earlier, Beniamino

Caravita (2002, 25-26) had written that "[a]lthough this reform [that of 2001] was hotly

debated, it adapts Italy to the phenomena of regionalization and federalization of public

powers." Caravita goes on to note that the reform has created institutions in what he

identifies as "the new more 'federal' Italy … " (our emphasis). More recently, Tommaso

Edoardo Frosini (2009, 1) has suggested that "[W]ith the 2001 reform … Italy has taken

its first steps toward a federal system. In fact, Italy has gone from a regional system in

which [the] central government enjoyed all the powers combined with a limited role for

local government to a system that can best be defined as 'federalist like' (our emphasis). It

is not federal, but 'federalist like' "because the federalisation process has not yet been

completed … ". In their excellent overview of developments in the analysis of virtually

all dimensions of federalism, Ehtisham Ahmad and Giorgio Brosio (2006, 1) write: "In

unitary states such as Spain and Italy, quasi-federal constructs have been adopted", thus

acknowledging the unitary character of Italy, but with a twist that mimics those of the

aforementioned scholars. A more or less general consensus is nicely captured by Lucio

Levi's (2009, 6) characterization of that twist as "Italy's zigzag path to federalism."

In an earlier paper (Breton and Fraschini, 2003) on vertical competition in Italy, we

took as given that the Republic was a unitary state – a state in which all powers are

4

constitutionally owned by the center even if some of these powers had been decentralized

to the periphery3 – but that the presence of what we identified as "institutional

commitment" devices, practices, and/or conventions allowed competition between

governments located at different jurisdictional tiers to generate efficient decentralization

equilibrium outcomes that were stable, in the sense that they did not unravel through

arbitrary repossessions of powers by the authorities at the center whenever competition

was deemed by these authorities to be unfavorable to them.

Let us now examine in more detail the three conditions just mentioned: a)

decentralization of powers; b) asymmetry in the design, implementation, and

administration of policies; and c) vertical competition over powers. In one form or

another, these conditions are to be found in all federal governmental systems, but also in

bona fide decentralized unitary states such as France and Spain. These conditions cannot

therefore tell us whether Italy is a federal or a quasi-federal state. Nevertheless, the

question of whether a country such as Italy is a federal or quasi-federal state is not only

interesting in itself, it is important for an accurate understanding of federalism. In other

words, states that are formally identified as federal differ from each other in all sorts of

ways regarding matters that define governance, and they vary over time in the degree to

which they are federal. It is therefore possible that countries that are not formally

recognized as federal may, by the creation and the re-structuring of some institutions of

governance, become de facto federal states.

As should soon become clear, an understanding of federalism (and indeed of

political decentralization generally) must give pride of place to an analysis of the division 3 On the significance of the ownership of powers in the identification and classification of governmental systems, see Breton (2000).

5

of powers among the jurisdictional levels of governmental systems. To put it differently,

a model of the assignment of powers is needed. We will make use of the model proposed

by Breton and Anthony Scott in 1978, replacing the "constituent assembly" as the

equilibrating device in that model with vertical competition as in Breton (1996) and in

Breton and Fraschini (2003) – a conceptual substitution inspired by the work of Pierre

Salmon (1987a and b) on horizontal competition. The Breton-Scott model – now more

appropriately identified as the Organizational Cost model to acknowledge the

contributions of other students of political decentralization and federalism besides Breton

and Scott – has received the endorsement of distinguished economic students of

federalism and decentralization such as James Buchanan and Marilyn Flowers (1980,

1987), Richard Musgrave, Peggy Musgrave, and Richard Bird (1987), Robert Inman and

Daniel Rubinfeld (1997) and Stanley Winer (2000).4 The model's building-blocks are in

the nature of organizational activities5: they are, on the demand side, the signaling of their

preferences by citizens plus their inter-communal mobility, and on the supply side, the

administration (the conduct or the running) of governments and the coordination of their

decisions. Of these four, only coordination, as it relates to powers, is explicitly required

to deal with the question of Italy's constitutional status. The other three activities are

concealed, but are effectively used by citizens and governments when engaging in

4 In the fifth (1980) and sixth (1987) editions of The Public Finances. An Introductory Textbook, Buchanan and Flowers, in their recommended "Supplementary Readings" at the end of the chapter on federalism, refer students to Breton and Scott (1978) as providing "a modern discussion of the economics of federalism", which we take as an authoritative endorsement of the theory. Musgrave, Musgrave and Bird (1987, 506) make use of the Breton-Scott model to offer an interesting "positive theory" of intergovernmental grants which again can be taken as an endorsement of the model. 5 In the private, as distinguished from the public sector, such activities have been identified by Coase (1937) as transactional activities that give rise to transaction costs.

6

vertical competition and are therefore at work in the background. The model we use can

therefore be thought of as a "reduced form" of the more general model, somewhat like the

one used by Breton, Scott and Fraschini (2011) to explain the different patterns of

environmental governance in Canada, the United States, and Italy.

We begin, in Section 2 subsection (2.1), with an analysis of powers and of the

attendant notion of heads of powers. In subsection (2.2) the problems that arise when an

exogenous shock alters a particular configuration of powers and heads of powers are

analysed. That leads to a discussion of coordination in subsection (2.3). In contemporary

Italy, the institutional framework that was put in place to implement intergovernmental

coordination is known as the System of Conferences. Section 3 is devoted to a

description, analysis, and critique of that System. In Section 4, we attempt to answer the

question which serves as title to the paper. Section 5 concludes.

2 Understanding Powers and Coordination

2.1 Powers and heads of powers

Given that our concern is strictly focused on whether Italy is a federal or quasi-federal

state, we restrict ourselves to the division of powers between the central and the regional

governments. The evidence presented in the Introduction related to the division of powers

in Italy is sufficient to establish that such a division exists, but is silent regarding the

problems that are attached to that division.

7

A power is the authority granted to, or acquired by, a public or a private body to

legislate, regulate and/or have a general capacity to act in particular areas or domains.

Virtually all powers confer authority to act in more than one area.6 It is therefore

impossible to say a priori how a particular power will be sub-divided among the various

bodies in which authority to act may have been vested. In other words, it is impossible to

say how powers will be bundled under particular heads of powers, or how they will

become re-bundled after an exogenous disturbance. For example, in Canada the power to

define what is a crime and what constitutes criminal behaviour is assigned to the federal

government, while the responsibility for the implementation of criminal law is granted to

provincial governments, as is the responsibility for the maintenance of courts − except the

Supreme Court of Canada. This multi-dimensionality of powers is one reason why

concurrency is so widespread and why, under one heading or another, explicit or implicit

doctrines and/or rules of paramountcy are formulated and used. Furthermore, the many

dimensions are not fixed for all time − their number and their meaning change with

circumstances and the appearance of new problems. Thus the interpretation by the courts

of Section 91(2) (related to "Trade and Commerce") of The Constitution Act, 1867 −

Canada's Constitution − was altered by as much as 180 degrees over a century, essentially

through a re-definition of what constitutes "national" and "local" markets.

6 It is well to keep in mind that governments can act without having a constitutional power to do so. To illustrate, they can induce action by offering cash payments and/or in-kind support. For a discussion of alternatives to constitutional powers, see Breton and Salmon (2009, 176-179).

8

2.2 Edgeworth complementarity

We assume that the bundling of powers under particular heads is a response to forces

which can be analysed by using propositions derived from the model of Edgeworth

complementarity, as reformulated in terms of supermodularity by Paul Milgrom and John

Roberts (1995). In standard neo-classical economics, complementarity requires that

production functions (and preference orderings) reflect domain convexity (i.e. convexity

of the bundles), functional differentiability, continuity, and so on. With the supermodular

concept, one can drop these assumptions and use the idea of complementarity to give

theoretical content to notions such as "fit" and "system effects" (Milgrom and Roberts,

1995, 180). The approach has made it possible to account for clusters of characteristics or

of activities in business enterprises – characteristics or activities that, in other words, "fit"

together. The increased versatility leads to the following definition: "activities are

Edgeworth complements if doing (more of) any one of them increases the returns to doing

(more of) the others" (Milgrom and Roberts, 1995, 181, italics in original).

To apply the supermodular notion of Edgeworth complementarity to heads of

powers, we must adapt Milgrom and Robert's definition: powers are Edgeworth

complements if making a greater use of any one of them under a given head, increases

the authority of the others under that same head. That definition implies that the power to

legislate in matters related to education, for example, may give authority to design and

implement policies in respect of the size of classrooms, of the qualification of teachers, of

the textbooks to be used, of graduation eligibility, and so on. If the policies form clusters

whose elements "fit" together, they are Edgeworth complements and the rate of return

9

(the marginal value or benefit) on each one of them will be positively correlated to the

yield on all the others.

Edgeworth complementarity implies that a competitive invasion (say) of one policy

area by a government located at a different jurisdictional level will negatively affect the

value of all other policy domains under that head. In addition, we should expect that in

possibly many instances the degree of Edgeworth complementarity among powers that

continue to be domiciled in the head affected by the invasion will be different post-

invasion from what it was pre-invasion. It should therefore come as no surprise that a

competitive invasion will often be resisted and lead to the adoption of countervailing

defensive strategies, but it will also often lead to interjurisdictional negotiations and to

coordination. To form a view regarding the incidence of coordination compared to other

reactions, we must consider what coordination entails.

2.3 Coordination

It is useful to distinguish between two dimensions of coordination. The first can be

described as the coming to an agreement on a particular matter, such as resolving how the

flow of a cross-border river is to be maintained. The resulting agreement, like private

commercial contracts, are the product of negotiations, and like private contracts will be

incomplete simply because it is not possible to incorporate all future contingencies in the

agreements. In the case of private commercial contracts, contract law makes it possible to

address the problem. In the words of Michael Trebilcock (1993, 17): "… the law of

contracts … provide[s] a set of default or background rules where the explicit terms of a

10

contract are incomplete …". In the absence of the equivalent of contract law, the parties

to an agreement may decide that they will reconvene every three, five, or seven years to

review the agreement and deal with the contingencies that had not been foreseen when

the agreement was initially reached. Other procedures, such as mediation, arbitration, or

an appeal to an "outside" referee, may be used. Another approach is to do what was done

in Italy, namely to legislate a framework aimed at formalizing coordination among

government bodies. All of these procedures should be considered part of the process of

negotiation and are therefore part of the cost of coordination.

The second dimension of coordination pertains to implementation, that is to the

operation of the bodies that will carry out the activities needed to do the coordinating.

That too has costs. If sometimes the costs of reaching agreements can extend over time,

the costs of implementing agreements end only when the coordination ends. The total

cost of coordination will therefore be a function of the overall costs of negotiations and of

implementing the agreements these have generated. The negotiations, in turn, will be

more difficult – more costly – the greater the degree of Edgeworth complementarity

among powers located in the relevant heads of power and among the public policies

housed in the appropriate powers.7

7 For a discussion of other factors that affect coordination costs, see Breton (1996, especially pp. 209-213), Scott (2009), and Breton, Scott, and Fraschini (2011).

11

3 The System of Conferences

3.1 Foreword

At the end of Section 1, we noted that if Italy is to be identified as a federal or quasi-

federal state, it is because the System of Conferences functions in such a way as to permit

genuine coordination on matters of concern to all the autonomous actors operating at the

central and sub-national – regions, provinces, and communes – levels of the Italian

governmental system. In what follows, we begin (subsection 3.2) with a brief description

of the formal legislated framework of the System of Conferences. In a second subsection

(3.3), we briefly investigate how the System functions in practice and discuss what that

implies for the question of whether Italy is a federal or a quasi-federal state.

3.2 The legislated framework

The System of Conferences has been in existence for over a quarter of a century. It is

made up of three bodies:8

i) the Conferenza permanente tra lo Stato, le Regioni e le Province Autonome di Trento e

Bolzano – the Central Government-Regions Conference;

8 In fact, there is a fourth Conference which is not, however, considered a part of the System of Conferences, namely the Conference of the Regions. It is a "spontaneous body" – in that it is not a product of legislation – which facilitates coordination among the regions. That Conference also prepares the documents that are shared among the regions and then submitted to the Central Government-Regions Conference (under i).

12

ii) the Conferenza Stato-Città ed Autonomie Locali – the Central Government-Cities and

Local Governments Conference; and

iii) the Conferenza Unificata – the Unified Conference which brings together the

Conferences listed under i) and ii) to consider issues of common interest to regions,

provinces and municipalities.

The formal purpose of the Conferences is to enable coordination of decision-

making and policy implementation among governments located at different jurisdictional

tiers whenever events such as exogenous disturbances, new public policy demands, or

new manifestations of vertical competition make that necessary. In other words, the

Conferences exist to permit and even foster confrontation and deliberation among central,

regional and local governments with, as an objective, the generation of Acts – a

portemanteau expression that includes advices, agreements, accords, and other

instruments pertaining to the implementation of coordination. In particular, the

Conferences are intended to allow governments at all jurisdictional levels to search for

common viewpoints and to compromise on issues that are different in different parts of

the country.

In the matter of coming to a decision on whether Italy is a federal or quasi-federal

state, the Central Government-Regions Conference plays an all-important role. For this

reason, it is the Conference on which we focus most of our attention.9 That Conference

was established in 1983 by an Administrative Decree following an inquiry by the

Parliamentary Commission on Regional Issues. It is the body where coordination among

governments of the two jurisdictional levels that have legislative powers can be carried

9 Were we concerned with decentralization as distinguished from the federal status of the country, we would have had to pay more attention to the Conference listed under ii) in the text.

13

out – where, in other words, the regions can have a say in the decisions of the national

government's Cabinet on matters of common interest.

The Central Government-Regions Conference is made up of 22 members. To

appreciate who they are, it is useful to know that Italy is divided into 20 regions of which

5 are autonomous. Every region has a statute that serves as a regional constitution – 15

regions have ordinary statutes, while 5 have special statutes that grant them extended

autonomy. Each of the 20 regions has a president. One of the autonomous regions is

Trentino-Alto Adige / Südtirol which is constituted of 2 autonomous provinces (Trento

and Bolzano), each with its own president. All of these 22 presidents, however, are not

members of the Central Government-Regions Conference. Indeed, the two presidents of

the autonomous provinces of Trento and Bolzano hold the Presidency of the Autonomous

Region of Trentino-Alto Adige / Südtirol on a rotating basis. Thus, at any point in time,

the members of the Conference are: the presidents of the 19 regions (excluding the

president of the autonomous region of Trentino-Alto Adige / Südtirol); the 2 presidents of

the autonomous provinces of Trento and Bolzano (one of whom – on a rotating basis –

also represents the region of Trentino-Alto Adige / Südtirol); and the Minister for

Regional Affairs – appointed by the Prime Minister – who convenes and presides over

the Conference.

In 1988-89, the rules and procedures under which the Conference was to operate

were defined and its functions clarified. These were further extended in 1997. At the

same time, the advisory role of the Conference was strengthened by making it mandatory

for the national Cabinet to seek the opinion of the Conference in regard to all bills,

regulations, and decrees dealing with legislation relating to regional matters. Indeed,

14

Article 4 of Decree n. 281/1997 states that "the central government, the regions and the

autonomous provinces, implementing the principle of loyal cooperation, can conclude (at

the Conference level) accords in order to coordinate the exercise of their powers and

carry out activities of common interest." These accords are, however, not legally binding.

This fact notwithstanding, we underscore, as a harbinger of constitutional evolution in

Italy, a declaration (n. 31/2006) of the Constitutional Court to the effect that "the

principle of loyal cooperation" implies that the parties that sign an official accord are

bound by that commitment.

The Central Government-Regions Conference is also consulted on the general

criteria regulating the distribution of resources among the regions, on the determination

of parameters to be used for intersectoral planning, and is compulsorily consulted –

sitting as Unified Conference – on the Document of Economic and Financial Planning

and on the Bill of the Finance Act (the budget law). The Central Government-Regions

Conference must meet at least twice a year, and on a request of the regions and of the

autonomous provinces of Trento and Bolzano.10 Only rarely are decisions taken by

majority vote. They are generally unanimous for a reason noted below in subsection

(3.3).

In addition, in 2011 (legislative Decree n. 68), a permanent Conference for the

coordination of the public finances (Conferenza permanente per il coordinamento della

finanza pubblica) was created to promote, among a number of things, the reconciliation

of interests among the various levels of government involved in the implementation of

10 The Central Government-Cities and Local Governments Conferences must be convened at least every three months; and whenever the President deems it is necessary, or on request of the presidents of the Associazione Nazionale dei Comuni Italiani, (ANCI), the Unione delle Province Italiane (UPI), or the Unione Nazionale Comuni, Comunità ed Enti Montani (UNCEM).

15

the rules of fiscal federalism. That conference was placed under the jurisdiction of the

Unified Conference, but is autonomous from it. At present, the relationship between the

two bodies is far from clear.

The Central Government-Regions Conference meets, in a "Community Session", at

least every six months or at the request of the regions and the autonomous provinces to

deal with European issues of regional interest.

3.3 The System in practice

The 1997 reform – the one that extended the functions of the Central Government-Region

Conference – led to a significant increase in the number of meetings of that Conference

and in the number of Acts adopted – from a yearly average of 87 Acts in the eight years

preceding the reform to a yearly average of 262 Acts in the following fifteen years.11 The

activities of the Conference have also contributed to a significant reduction in litigation

before the Constitutional Court. This reduction is consistent with the view that following

the "disorientation" caused by the reform of 2001 (see Section 1), both the central and the

regional governments adopted rules and behaviours that have led to a greater degree of

coordination than hitherto (Bile, 2008).

The evidence is, however, somewhat ambiguous. In Section 2, we noted that

coordination is an activity or a sequence of activities that is costly. It follows that the

quantity and the quality of coordination will vary over time, over issues and subject

matters, and with changes in the "priors" of the persons involved. To illustrate, during the

11 Presidency of the Council of Ministers, http://www.statoregioni.it. – our calculations.

16

XIIIth Legislature (May 1996-May 2001), under the rule of left-of-centre national

Cabinets, the recommendations of the Conferences, especially those of the Unified

Conference, were taken to be binding by both the national Executive and Parliament;

whereas, during the XIVth Legislature (May 2001-April 2006), when national Cabinets

were right-of-centre, there were clashes within the Conferences, and the national

Executive often did not take into account the views expressed by the regions, or it tried to

act without the involvement of the regions, thus requiring interventions by the

Constitutional Court to generate by judicial decisions what coordination had failed to

achieve (Bin and Ruggiu, 2006, 921).

Another problem that reduces the effectiveness of the System of Conferences

generally and of the all-important Central Government-Regions Conference in particular

to act as agencies capable of generating the amount of coordination needed to address the

sort of problems discussed in Section 2, is a basic lack of symmetry. This manifests itself

in the fact that in that Conference, the regions can voice their opinions on the legislative

bills of the central government, but the latter, to avoid constitutional litigation, cannot ask

for a discussion, in the Conference, of the bills of the regional governments.

All in all, it seems almost impossible to dispute the proposition that the Central

Government-Regions Conference and the other Conferences are, in effect, advisory

bodies to the Executive of the national government: the latter convenes the Conferences,

chairs them, and sets the agenda as well as the time schedule for the submission of bills

and draft of legislative decrees. In other words, even if the law does specify that the

Central Government-Regions Conference must meet at least twice a year, and on a

request of the regions and of the autonomous provinces of Trento and Bolzano, it remains

17

that under current arrangements all Conferences are initiated by the national Executive

when it tables a bill, adopts a ministerial decree, proposes an allotment of funds, and so

on. It is also a fact that the national Executive often presents measures to the Conferences

so late that the latter do not have the time needed to analyze them and to submit

comments. As a consequence, the Conferences have in reality no decision-making power.

Moreover, "escapes" or "leakages" from the System of Conferences have recently

emerged. For example, the bill on fiscal federalism, approved in May 2009, was modified

by Parliament following suggestions made by the regional and local governments in

"political meetings" and not through the Unified Conference, which has merely taken

notice of the agreements made in those political meetings. Besides, in many instances the

regions, through the Conference of the Regions (which, to repeat, is not part of the

System of Conferences), conclude accords and agreements directly with the ministries,

accords and agreements that, if the System of Conferences was working effectively as a

coordination mechanism, should be ratified by the Central Government-Regions

Conference. Indeed, a reading of the Minutes of the Conference meetings suggests that

differences among the regions seldom emerge at the level of the Conference, because

conflicts have been taken up and resolved in the Conference of the Regions. In addition,

before each session of the Conference, the Secretariat organizes meetings between

officials of the national Cabinet and of the regions to discuss technical issues and to find

agreed-upon solutions. Generally, only when the main problems have been resolved are

the relevant questions put on the order paper of the Conference, which then speedily

deals with the topics on the agenda, taking notice of the work accomplished in the

18

technical meetings and concentrating on only few issues. That is the rationale for the

view that the Conference is where the parties meet to affirm decisions made elsewhere!

4 Attempting an Answer to the Title's Question

All transactions, including bargaining and negotiation undertaken with the aim of

achieving coordination in regards to, say, the formulation and implementation of policies

or the discovery of an appropriate "fit" – as defined in subsection (2.2) – of powers under

one or more heads of powers, are conducted in particular frameworks or protocols.

Frameworks can be legally designed institutions, such as the Italian System of

Conferences briefly examined in subsection (3.2); but they can take any of a number of

configurations. To illustrate, Richard Simeon (1972) has convincingly argued, after

arduous field work, that in Canada the protocol is essentially one of "diplomatic"

interaction among the executive branches of the federal and provincial governments – the

Canadian mode of coordination that Donald Smiley (1970, 1974, and 1980, especially

Chapter 4) has felicitously called "executive federalism". The various protocols in which

transactions are conducted will generally be country specific, and are likely to display

weaknesses of various sorts.

In regard to the Italian System of Conferences these weaknesses have been briefly

described in subsection (3.3). To summarize, we noted that the legal framework appears

to have evolved over the years in a way that grants more authority to the central

government and less to the regions. It is even possible that what we identified as

achievements of Central Government-Regions Conference, namely the increased output

19

of Acts following the 1997 reform, and the reduction in cases litigated before the

Constitutional Court, could be due to the increased authority of the national government –

an increased authority which generates an increase of one-on-one deals.

It is therefore our judgement that Italy is not yet a federal or even a quasi-federal

state – it is even possible that the country is less decentralized than what the formal

evidence noted in the Introduction seems to suggest. Being aware that it is always

difficult to prove a negative, we know that our judgement must be tentative. To put

differently, we are aware that documenting the absence of a characteristic of federalism –

one, however, which is neither necessary nor sufficient to corroborate that a

governmental system is federal – does not prove the inexistence of federalism; it only

voids one argument among others in support of its existence.

5 Conclusion

Political decentralization and federalism are fundamentally concerned with the division

of powers among the jurisdictional levels of governmental systems. We therefore began

our analysis with a definition of powers and a discussion of the complex manner they

relate to each other. That complexity implies, we argued, that intergovernmental

coordination relating to the division of powers is central to a question such as whether

Italy is a federal or quasi-federal state. We made use of a "reduced form" of the

organizational cost model developed by Breton and Scott (1978) in which all

organizational activities – except coordination – operate in the background.

20

Coordination is embedded in "frameworks" of various sorts. In the case of Italy,

that framework is a legislated System of Conferences. We briefly described that system

and depicted how it actually functions. We concluded that the actual modus operandi is

such that Italy is not yet a federal or even a quasi-federal state, while at the same time

acknowledging the inherent difficulty of proving a negative.

21

Acknowledgments

We would like to thank Giorgio Brosio, Giampaolo Parodi, Pierre Salmon, and Anthony

Scott for helpful comments pertaining to the logic of the paper and to our understanding

of certain historical facts. The usual disclaimer applies.

References

Ahmad, Ehtisham and Giorgio Brosio (2006), "Introduction: fiscal federalism – a review

of developments in the literature and policy", in Ehtisham Ahmad and Giorgio

Brosio (eds.), Handbook of Fiscal Federalism, Cheltenham, UK and Northampton,

MA, USA: Edward Elgar, 1-29.

Bile, Franco (2008), "La giustizia costituzionale nel 2007", Annual press conference,

Rome, 14 February, www.cortecostituzionale.it.

Bin, Roberto and Ilenia Ruggiu (2006), "La rappresentanza territoriale in Italia: Una

proposta di riforma del sistema delle conferenze, passando per il definitivo

abbandono del modello Camera delle Regioni", Le Istituzioni del Federalismo, (6),

903-954.

22

Breton, Albert (1996), Competitive Governments. An Economic Theory of Politics and

Public Finance, New York: Cambridge University Press.

Breton, Albert (2000), "Federalism and Decentralization: Ownership Rights and the

Superiority of Federalism", Publius. The Journal of Federalism, 30(2), 1-16.

Breton, Albert and Anthony Scott (1978), The Economic Constitution of Federal States,

Toronto: University of Toronto Press.

Breton, Albert and Angela Fraschini (2003), "Vertical Competition in Unitary States: The

Case of Italy", Public Choice, 114(1-2), 57-77.

Breton, Albert and Pierre Salmon (2009), "Compliance in Decentralized Environmental

Governance", in Albert Breton, Giorgio Brosio, Silvana Dalmazzone, and

Giovanna Garrone (eds.), Governing the Environment. Salient Institutional Issues,

Cheltenham, UK and Northampton, MA, USA: Edward Elgar, 174-207.

Breton, Albert, Anthony Scott, and Angela Fraschini (2011), "Explaining Differences in

Environmental Governance Patterns between Canada, Italy, and the United States",

in Randall Morck (ed.), Recreating Canada. Essays in Honour of Paul Weiler,

Montreal and Kingston: McGill-Queen's University Press, 67-87.

23

Buchanan, James M. and Marilyn R. Flowers (1980 and 1987), The Public Finances. An

Introductory Textbook, Homewood: Irwin.

Caravita, Beniamino (2002), "Italy: Toward a Federal State?", in Special Triple Issue:

Themes of the International Conference on Federalism 2002, www.forumfed.org,

25-26.

Coase, Ronald H. (1937), "The Nature of the Firm", Economica, New Series, 4(16), 386-

405. Reprinted in George J. Stigler and Kenneth E. Boulding, eds., (1952),

Readings in Price Theory, Homewood: Irwin, 331-351.

Frosini, Tommaso E. (2009), "Introduction to Italian Fiscal Federalism",

www.forumfed.org, 1-6.

Inman, Robert P. and Daniel L. Rubinfeld (1997), "The Political Economy of

Federalism", in Dennis Mueller (ed.), Perspective on Public Choice. A Handbook,

New York: Cambridge University Press, 73-105.

Levi, Lucio (2009), "Italy's Fiscal Devolution Moves It Towards Federalism",

Federations, 8(1), 5-7.

Milgrom, Paul and John Roberts (1995), "Complementarities and Fit: Strategy, Structure,

and Organizational Change in Manufacturing", Journal of Accounting and

Economics, 19(2-3), 179-208.

24

Musgrave, Richard A., Peggy B. Musgrave, and Richard M. Bird (1987), Public Finance

in Theory and Practice, Toronto: McGraw-Hill Ryerson.

Palermo, Francesco and Jens Woelk (2007), "Italy Takes the Slow Boat to Federalism",

Federations, 7(1), 17-18.

Palermo, Francesco and Alex Wilson (2013), "The Dynamics of Decentralization in Italy:

Towards a Federal Solution?", European Diversity and Autonomy Papers,

EDAP/04. at www.eurac.edu/edap.

Pola, Giancarlo (2008), "1948-2008: The Ups and Downs of a 60-years-long

Decentralization (?) Process in Italy", (IACFS Conference. Barcelona, September

19-20), 86-103, www.federalismi.it.

Salmon Pierre (1987a), "The Logic of Pressure groups and the Structure of the Public

Sector", in Albert Breton, Gianluigi Galeotti, Pierre Salmon, and Ronald Wintrobe

(eds.), Villa Colombella Papers on Federalism, European Journal of Political

Economy, 3(1-2), 55-86.

Salmon, Pierre (1987b), "Decentralization as an Incentive Scheme", Oxford Review of

Economic Policy, 3(2), 24-43.

25

Scott, Anthony (2009), "Contracts in the Vertical Assignment of Powers over the

Environment". In Albert Breton, Giorgio Brosio, Silvana Dalmazzone, and

Giovanna Garrone (eds.), Governing the Environment: Salient Institutional Issues,

Cheltenham and Northampton: Edward Elgar, 13-42.

Simeon, Richard (1972), Federal-Provincial Diplomacy. The Making of Recent Policy in

Canada, Toronto and Buffalo: University of Toronto Press.

Smiley, Donald V. (1970), "Canadian Federalism and the Resolution of Federal-

Provincial Conflict". In Frederick Vaughan, Patrick Kyba, and Onkar Prasad

Dwivedi (eds.), Contemporary Issues in Canadian Politics, Scarborough: Prentice-

Hall of Canada, 48-66.

Smiley, Donald V. (1974), "Federal-Provincial Conflict in Canada", Publius: The Journal

of Federalism, 4, 7-24.

Smiley, Donald V. (1980), Canada in Question: Federalism in the Eighties, Third

Edition, Toronto: McGraw-Hill Ryerson.

Trebilcock, Michael J. (1993), The Limits of Freedom of Contract, Cambridge, MA and

London, UK: Harvard University Press.

26

Winer, Stanley L. (2000), "On the Reassignment of Fiscal Powers in a Federal State", in

Gianluigi Galeotti, Pierre Salmon, and Ronald Wintrobe (eds.), Competition and

Structure. The Political Economy of Collective Decisions: Essays in Honor of

Albert Breton, Cambridge, UK and New York: Cambridge University Press, 150-

173.

Recent working papers

The complete list of working papers is can be found at http://polis.unipmn.it/index.php?cosa=ricerca,polis

*Economics Series **Political Theory and Law Al.Ex Series

Q Quaderni CIVIS

2016 n.234* Albert Breton and Angela Fraschini: Is Italy a Federal or even a Quasi-Federal State?

2016 n.233** Maria Luisa Bianco, Flavio Ceravolo, Giovanna Garrone e Guido Ortona: Crisi economica e disoccupazione giovanile: valutazione del consenso verso politichedi intervento pubblico

2015 n.232* Michele G. Giuranno and Manuela Mosca: Political realism and models of the state – Antonio de Viti de Marco and the origins of Public Choice

2015 n.231** Guido Napolitano and Francesco Ingravalle: La liberalità. Versi sciolti attribuibili a Vincenzo Gioberti

2015 n.230** Francesco Ingravalle and Giuseppe Scalici (eds): Filippo Giordano Bruno: Cabala del Cavallo Pegaseo con l'Aggiunta dell'Asino Cillenico

2015 n.229** Matteo Cannonero et al. (DRASD): OPAL – Osservatorio per le autonomie locali N.7/2015

2015 n.228* Michele G. Giuranno and Rongili Biswas: Internal migration and public policy

2015 n.227* Giuseppe Di Liddo and Michele G. Giuranno: Strategic delegation under the subsidiarity principle

2015 n.226* Giampaolo Arachi, Giuseppe Di Liddo and Michele G. Giuranno: Cooperazione locale in Italia: le Unioni di Comuni

2015 n.225* Guido Ortona: A commonsense assessment of Arrow's theorem

2015 n.224* Michele Giuranno and Antonella Nocco: Trade tariff, wage gap and public spending

2015 n.223* Giuseppe Di Liddo and Michele Giuranno: Asymmetric yardstick competition and municipal cooperation

2015 n.222** Maria Bottiglieri: Il diritto al cibo adeguato. Tutela internazionale, costituzionale e locale di un diritto fondamentale “nuovo”

2015 n.221** Piera Maria Vipiana and Matteo Timo: Le direttive UE del 2014 in tema di appalti pubblici e concessioni

2015 n.220 Gianna Lotito, Matteo Migheli and Guido Ortona: Competition and its effects oncooperation – An experimental test

2015 n.219 Marco Novarese and Viviana Di Giovinazzo: Not Through Fear But Through Habit. Procrastination, cognitive capabilities and self-confidence

2014 n.218** Nicola Dessì et al. (DRASD): OPAL – Osservatorio per le autonomie locali N.6/2014

2014 n.217* Roberto Ippoliti: Efficienza tecnica e geografia giudiziaria

2014 n.216** Elena Ponzo et al. (DRASD): OPAL – Osservatorio per le autonomie locali N.5/2014

2014 n.215 Gianna Lotito, Anna Maffioletti and Marco Novarese: Are better students really less overconfident? - A preliminary test of different measures

2014 n.214* Gloria Origgi, Giovanni B. Ramello and Francesco Silva: Publish or Perish. Cause e conseguenze di un paradigma

2014 n.213** Andrea Patanè et al. (DRASD): OPAL – Osservatorio per le autonomie locali N.4/2014

2014 n.212** Francesco Ingravalle et al.: L’evento. Aspetti e problemi